covid
Buscar en
BRQ Business Research Quarterly
Toda la web
Inicio BRQ Business Research Quarterly A comparative analysis of profit inefficiency and productivity convergence betwe...
Journal Information
Share
Share
Download PDF
More article options
Visits
460
Regular article
Open Access
Available online 15 March 2019
A comparative analysis of profit inefficiency and productivity convergence between Taiwanese and Chinese banks
Visits
460
Xiang Chena, Tsu-Tan Fub,
Corresponding author
tfu@econ.sinica.edu.tw

Corresponding author.
, Jia-Ching Juoc, Ming-Miin Yud
a China Academy of Financial Research, Zhejiang University of Finance & Economics, Hangzhou, China
b Department of Economics, Soochow University, Taipei, Taiwan
c Department of International Business, Lunghwa University of Science and Technology, Taoyuan County, Taiwan
d Department of Transportation Science, National Taiwan Ocean University, Keelung, Taiwan
This item has received

Under a Creative Commons license
Received 07 May 2018. Accepted 06 February 2019
Article information
Abstract
Full Text
Bibliography
Download PDF
Statistics
Tables (6)
Table 1. Variable specification.
Table 2. Summary statistics of inputs and outputs, 2010–2014.
Table 3. Meta-profit inefficiency and its decomposition.
Table 4. Group-specific profit inefficiency and its decomposition.
Table 5. Profit inefficiency and its components’ gaps.
Table 6. Group-specific profit LPI πL, metafrontier profit LPI πL* and their gap (πLG).
Show moreShow less
Abstract

To insure a proper and meaningful productivity assessment of DMUs with different production technology, this paper develops a difference-based profit metafrontier Luenberger productivity indicator. Adopting the proposed model, we empirically measure the profit inefficiency and examine the profit productivity convergence for samples banks consisting of 31 Taiwanese banks and 50 Chinese city banks over 2010–2014. Empirical results show that Chinese banks perform better in profit efficiency than Taiwanese banks. While Chinese banks have better technology in profit creation than Taiwanese banks, the latter may reap much higher profit gain than the former if they can adopt the profit metafrontier. The results of the profit metafrontier Luenberger productivity indicator analysis show that both Chinese and Taiwanese banks have experienced declines in profit productivity. However, the results also indicate a divergence in productivity growth for Chinese city banks and a convergent productivity growth for Taiwanese banks.

Keywords:
Luenberger indicator
Metafrontier
Profit productivity
Bank performance
Full Text
Introduction

To accommodate a potential measuring problem of the ratio-based Malmquist Productivity Index (MPI) which fails to model the distance function with both input contraction and output expansion, (Chambers et al., 1996) develop the difference-based Luenberger productivity indicator (LPI) with the directional distance function. The duality between the directional distance function and the profit function provides the LPI to be a useful mean for performance assessment when profitability is the overall goal of firms. LPI has received much attention recently for various applications (Briec and Kerstens, 2009; Epure et al., 2010; Lansink et al., 2015; Lin et al., 2017; Juo et al., 2015; Boussemart et al., 2018). Briec and Kerstens (2009) extend the Luenberger framework of Chambers et al. (1996) by diagnosing the economic conditions under which infeasibility may occur and exploring solutions. Epure et al. (2010) use LPI to analyze changes in productivity and efficiency of Spanish banks and decompose this indicator into pure efficiency, scale change, and congestion change. Lansink et al. (2015)() develop primal and dual versions of the Luenberger productivity growth, depending on the dynamic directional distance function and cost minimization. Lin et al. (2017) also set up a cost-oriented LPI and provide its decomposition. Furthermore, Juo et al. (2015) enhance the profit-oriented LPI by giving a full picture of the sources of productivity change, whereas Boussemart et al. (2018) provide an extended decomposition of LPI on Chinese healthcare sector assessment.

Although LPI has already defined many extensions, to our knowledge the current versions of LPI still fail to consider decision-making units’ (DMUs’) productivity differentials across different groups where they may separately operate under different technologies. A direct comparison may not be valid if DMUs operate under different production technologies (O’Donnell et al., 2008). To make an analogous comparison of efficiency or productivity indices of DMUs across different technology groups, it is necessary to build a common technology frontier, called metafrontier, for all DMUs.

Battese et al. (2004) and O’Donnell et al. (2008) develop the metafrontier production function models that allows for the possibility of technological differences across groups in order to measure comparable efficiency scores of DMUs among these groups. Such a metafrontier framework has been extended to measure productivity change over time using the ratio-based MPI by studies such as Chen et al. (2009), Oh (2010), Oh and Lee (2010), Chen and Yang (2011). They are however still subject to the above-mentioned limitation embedded in the ratio-based MPI. To accommodate such limitation under the metafrontier framework, this paper attempts to fill this research gap by developing a profit metafrontier LPI and applies the proposed model to assess the performance of profit efficiency and productivity changes on the banking industries of Taiwan and China.

The banking industries in Taiwan and China have different technologies due to their political separation since 1945. With the establishment of the cross-strait financial supervision memorandum of understanding (MOU) and the Economic Cooperation Framework Agreement (ECFA), Taiwanese and Chinese banks now have the opportunity for offering financial services to companies on the other side of the Taiwan Strait. Facing huge market opportunities for investment and financial activities in China, Taiwanese banks are looking to enlarge their scale of operations and taking advantage of cheaper labor costs in China. The incentives for Chinese banks may rest on the good opportunities to adopt a better operating technology as well as the rich experiences of financial development from Taiwan. Mutual benefits are expected if both parties can eliminate market restrictions and collaborate in accessing better production technology and a larger-scale financial market (for Taiwan's banks). However, such benefits are unpredictable without extensive information of the operation performance of banks in these two economies. To obtain comparable results of a bank's productivity and efficiency in China and Taiwan, the adoption of the metafrontier framework should work well.

Previous studies have investigated the efficiency and productivity performance between Chinese and Taiwanese banks under the production or cost metafrontier framework. Chen and Yang (2011) apply the meta production frontier to examine the technical efficiency of banks in Taiwan and China, whereas Huang and Fu (2013) develop the cost metafrontier function to compare the cost efficiency and technology gap. Huang et al. (2015) apply the metafrontier cost MPI to assess the dynamic banking performances between China and Taiwan.

Despite profitability is the ultimate goal for most of banks, we find very few profit efficiency studies that compare profit performances across groups or regimes. Mulwa and Emrouznejad (2013) first introduce profit efficiency analysis under the metafrontier framework. Fu et al. (2016) consider risk-based metafrontier profit efficiency model to analyze bank performances in Taiwan and China. While measuring profit efficiency under metafrontier framework, both studies only employ a single-period metafrontier profit model and fail to consider the changes of profit efficiency and productivity over time. Juo et al. (2015) are the first to utilize LPI for measuring the dynamic profit-oriented productivity performance of Taiwanese banks. They combine the Nerlovian profit efficiency measurement with the conventional LPI and give a full picture of the source of profit productivity change. However, unless their model can be extended to a metafrontier framework, it is otherwise inadequate for comparing firms’ performance from production groups with different production technology.

Profit inefficiency is an indicator to measure manager's ability to adopt the best input-output bundle for profit maximization given input-output prices faced by DMUs. The profit loss due to profit inefficiency is defined as the difference between maximized profit and observed profit. The input–output bundle of the profit maximization may be a benchmark for less profit inefficiency DMUs to emulate if they face similar prices as the benchmark DMU does. It is a general interest to decompose profit inefficiency into technical inefficiency and allocative inefficiency. The directional vector using current input–output for projecting observed point on production frontier can help identify an appropriate measure of technical inefficiency. The allocative inefficiency could be biased without an appropriate technical inefficiency measure. Since the input-output bundle of a DMU varies over time, thus it is also necessary to assure the directional vector to be time variant for inducing appropriate technical and allocative inefficiencies over time. The drawback of adopting time invariant directional vector has also been raised by previous studies. Balk (2018) criticized that the time invariant directional vector used in Juo et al. (2015) resulted in a failure to provide a meaningful interpretation to price effect, a component of productivity decomposition. Aparicio et al. (2012) pointed out that a time invariant directional vector would cause an inappropriate measure of technical efficiency. A time variant directional vector is thus necessary for an appropriate measurement of the profit oriented LPI and its productivity decomposition.

In this study we therefore extend the profit-oriented LPI of Juo et al. (2015) into a metafrontier framework with a time variant directional vector. This newly developed metafrontier profit-oriented LPI measures the profit productivity and efficiency performance across banks in Taiwan and China. The measures for the gaps in productivity help us examine the convergence between the group profit frontier and the profit metafrontier. These analyses have not been expressively accounted for in the LPI literature. We hence empirically apply the proposed profit metafrontier LPI to measure the profit efficiency and productivity of 31 Taiwanese banks and 50 Chinese city banks in the period 2010–2014.

Compared to the previous literature, we make three contributions to the application of profit analysis. First, we develop a new metafrontier profit-oriented LPI. Our proposed model not only considers a profit-oriented productivity comparison between two groups due to group-specific heterogeneity, but also combines the intertemporal changes in productivity, thus offering a supplement to the studies of Juo et al. (2015) and Fu et al. (2016). In addition, our proposed indicator is distinct from that of Juo et al. (2015) on the assumption of using a direction vector. We propose a time-variant direction vector which avoids the problems mentioned by Balk (2018) and Aparicio et al. (2012). Second, the proposed LPI model successfully accommodates the problem and limitation embedded in the ratio-based MPI under the metafrontier framework. Third, this study is the first to empirically analyze the profit-oriented efficiency and productivity changes of Taiwanese and Chinese city banks by the proposed method.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Second section defines the methodology used to measure the profit inefficiency and profit LPI under the group frontier and metafrontier technologies. Third section lists the definitions of variables and data statistics. Forth section is the empirical results and discussion. The conclusion follows in fifth section.

MethodologyGroup-specific technologies, meta-technologies, and profit inefficiency

This study considers the panel data of the hth (h=1, 2, …, H) production group – for example, of a country or an industry. Assume that DMUs at period t use the input vector xt (xt∈R+N) to produce an output vector yt (yt∈R+M). This study defines its production technology set at period t for the hth group as follow: Sht=xt,yt:xt   can produce yt, where Sht is assumed to be convex and closed.

The directional distance function (DDF) is defined by:

where the directional vector gt=−gxt,+gyt, gxt∈R+N, and gyt∈R+M denotes that this function shifts by simultaneously contracting inputs and expanding outputs, so as to reach the production frontier. Thus, Dht→xt,yt;−gxt,gyt also represents the degree of technical inefficiency (TIht).

The profit function is defined for the technology Sht as:

Eq. (2) implies that maximum profit is greater or equal to the observed profit:

The relationship of profit inefficiency measure (πIht) and technical inefficiency measure (TIht) can be expressed as:

We note that profit inefficiency measure, πIht, or the difference in maximal profit and observed profit, is normalized by the sum of ptgyt+wtgxt, following the definition of Nerlovian profit efficiency (Chambers et al., 1998). The right-hand side of Eq. (3), Dht→xt,yt;−gxt,gyt, measures technical inefficiency. The gap in the inequality Eq. (3) reflects the residual inefficiency of profit, and so we define allocative inefficiency (AIht) as:

Rearranging Eq. (4), profit inefficiency can be decomposed into two sources as:

From Eq. (5), it can be seen that profit inefficiency is a summation of technical inefficiency and allocative inefficiency. The former (TIht) measures production of less outputs yielded from excessive inputs. The latter (AIht) results from the inappropriate output-input mix in light of their given prices.

The meta-technology at period t can be defined as the convex hull of group technologies. This study assumes that all members in each group operate under a common potential frontier, the meta-technology set, i.e. S*t=convex hull(S1t∪S2t∪S3t∪⋯∪SHt).

Under the meta-technology, we similarly define DDF along the direction gt=−gxt,+gyt as:

When a DMU operates under the production metafrontier, its profit function at period t is:

The meta-Nerlovian profit inefficiency measure is defined as:

Similarly, we can decompose meta-profit inefficiency πI*t into meta-technical inefficiency and meta-allocative inefficiency as follows.

The difference between the meta-profit inefficiency πI*t and the group-specific profit inefficiency πIht is defined the profit inefficiency gap (πIhG):

The profit inefficiency gap, πIhG, measures the incremental degree of potential profit inefficiency if a DMU operates under the metafrontier instead of its group-specific frontier. By comparing Eqs. (8) to (3), we also can define πIhG as the difference in DMUs’ maximum profits between operating under the metafrontier and under the group frontier. The positive (negative) value of πIhG indicates that the maximum profit under the profit metafrontier is higher (lower) than that under the group-specific profit frontier. Therefore, the higher the value of πIhG a DMU has, the more profit it could gain if it operates using the metafrontier instead of the group frontier.

The profit inefficiency gap (πIhG) can be further decomposed into technical inefficiency gap (TIhG) and allocative inefficiency gap (AIhG):

Here, TIhG and AIhG denote the respective technical inefficiency gap and allocative inefficiency gap, while TIhG measures the distance of the meta-technology frontier to the group technology frontier, and its value is always positive since the group technology frontiers are enveloped by the meta-technology frontier. The AIhG allocative inefficiency gap measures the difference between the meta-allocative inefficiency and the group-specific allocative inefficiency. It is also regarded as DMU's pure maximum profit difference between the metafrontier and group frontier after excluding the profit gain attributed to the technology adoption of the metafrontier over the group frontier. The value of AIhG could be positive, negative, or zero.

Group-specific technologies, meta-technologies, and profit LPI

The LPI introduced by Chambers et al. (1996) is used to evaluate a difference-based productivity change. This indicator is defined and calculated by the quantity distance function.

This study defines the profit-oriented LPI between periods t and t+1 for the hth group as:

Here, we assume the directional vector to be time-variant gt=−gxt,+gyt=−xhjt,yhjt,1 and gtgt+1. Thus, the value of the production size (directional vector times prices of inputs and outputs) will be different over time. This profit LPI implies productivity progress, regress, or constant if its value is positive, negative, or zero, respectively.

Under the metafrontier technology, the meta-profit LPI (πL*t,t+1) can be similarly defined as the group-specific profit LPI, except that period t's (also period t+1's) group-specific profit functions πhtpt,wt,πht+1pt+1,wt+1 are replaced by meta profit functions (π*tpt,wt,π*t+1pt+1,wt+1). Therefore, the meta-profit productivity, referred to as meta-technology, can be defined the same as those equations for the group-specific profit LPI.

For a DMU, we define the profit LPI gap of the hth group-specific frontier to the metafrontier as the difference ratio for the profit productivity change between the meta-technology (πL*t,t+1) and its own chosen group-specific technology (πL*t,t+1) of Eq. (12):

If πL*t,t+1>πLht,t+1 (πL*t,t+1<πLht,t+1), then profit productivity growth between periods t and t+1 is faster (slower) under the meta-technology than that under the group-specific technology, which means a divergence (convergence) of the group-specific frontier from (toward) the meta-profit frontier. We define this gap (πLhG) as the catch-up index. This catch-up index indicates the difference in the speed of productivity change between group-specific frontiers and the meta-frontier for different banking industries over time. It implies convergence if πLhG<0, divergence if πLhG>0, and a constant growth gap if πLhG=0. The catch-up index is important information to examine whether the productivity of a banking industry can outperform the productivity of another banking industry in the future.

Suppose banking industry A has a negative catch-up index value for the last t few years. We thus expect the productivity of banks in banking industry A is getting closer (convergent) to the metafrontier over time. On the contrary, banking industry B exhibits divergence in consecutive years, implying that these banks’ productivity is moving away over time from the metafrontier. We may conclude that the productivity growth of banks in banking industry A will outperform those banks in banking industry B in the future, even though the current productivity level of the former is lower than the latter.

It should be noted that the group-specific and metafrontier profit LPI can be decomposed into components of technical efficiency change, allocative efficiency change, technical change, and price effect. In our empirical estimation. We also adopt the short-run variable profit function, instead of the long-run profit function.2

Data and variables

The sample data consist of 50 Chinese city commercial banks and 31 Taiwanese banks over the period 2010–2014. We do not include those state-owned and joint-stock Chinese banks, because these banks are operating across provinces in China and have a much larger scale of operations than Taiwanese banks. Chinese city banks operate mainly within a province, whereas Taiwanese banks provide service in Taiwan. Since Taiwan's geographical size is similar to the size of a province in China, a performance comparison using samples of Chinese city banks and Taiwanese banks can avoid the problem of great scale diversity and may provide meaningful managerial implications.

This study follows the intermediation approach for the specification of inputs and outputs. It assumes that the bank collects deposits to transform them with labor and capital into loans and other earning assets. Following Fu et al. (2016) and Berger and Humphrey (1997), this study considers two outputs: financial investments (y1) and total loans (y2). The investments are defined as other earning assets, including financial assets, securities, and equity investments. The corresponding unit price of the investments (p1) is the ratio of the investments’ revenue to the total investments Total loans consist of all types of loans issued that generate a given amount of interest income. The corresponding unit price of loans (p2) is the ratio of the raised amounts of interest income to the total loans.

This study specifies two inputs and one quasi-fixed input. The input vector includes financial funds (x1) and labor (x2). The quasi-fixed input (f1) is physical capital, which is the net amount of fixed assets. Financial funds (x1) are defined as deposits and borrowed funds. This input always accounts for the highest percentage of total costs in a bank, but it also generates interest and other financial expenses. Thus, the corresponding unit price (w1) is calculated as the ratio of financial expenses to financial funds. Labor (x2) is defined as the number of employees, while the corresponding unit price (w2) is calculated as a ratio of personal expenses to the total number of employees. Table 1 defines all the variables.

Table 1.

Variable specification.

Variable  Name  Definition 
Input variables
x1  Financial funds  Including deposits and borrowed funds (millions of USD) 
x2  Labor  Number of employees (persons) 
Quasi-fixed input variable
f1  Physical capital  Net amount of fixed assets (millions of USD) 
Output variables
y1  Investments  Including financial assets, securities, and equity investments (millions of USD) 
y2  Loans  Including loans and discounts (millions of USD) 
Input price variables
w1  Price of funds  Interest expenses divided by total deposits (USD million/USD million) 
w2  Price of labor  Personal expenses divided by number of employees (unit: USD million per person) 
Output price variables
p1  Price of investments  Revenue from investments divided by investment (USD million/USD million) 
p2  Price of loans  Revenue from loans divided by loans (USD million/USD million) 

Table 2 presents summary statistics of the sample banks. The column for the annual growth rate in Table 2 clearly shows that both Taiwanese and Chinese city banks experience positive growth in outputs and inputs, whereas the growth in China outperforms that in Taiwan during the sample period. The output structure between the two groups presents a significant difference, as the value share of investment to loans is about 1:1 in China compared to that of 1:3 in Taiwan. It implies that there are different strategies on funding allocation between banks in Taiwan and China. Moreover, a 5–6 times higher output growth rate in China than in Taiwan also indicates faster growing financial demand in China, which may attract Taiwanese bankers to invest in China.

Table 2.

Summary statistics of inputs and outputs, 2010–2014.

Variables  20102011201220132014Annual growth rate 
  Mean  Std.  Mean  Std.  Mean  Std.  Mean  Std.  Mean  Std.  Mean 
Y1: investments (USD million)
Taiwan  6267  6907  5838  6627  6595  6989  7013  7144  7299  7303  3.05% 
China  5504  8234  6925  10,183  9408  12,799  12,320  16,101  14,920  19,794  19.94% 
Y2: loans (USD million)
Taiwan  19,081  17,787  19,682  18,127  21,619  19,602  21,838  19,477  22,473  19,744  3.27% 
China  6577  9045  8318  11,095  10,342  13,596  12,459  16,042  14,683  9967  16.06% 
X1: financial funds (USD million)
Taiwan  25,733  23,410  26,038  23,141  28,687  25,299  29,478  26,500  30,233  26,358  3.22% 
China  11,176  13,966  13,593  16,238  16,687  19,392  20,474  23,013  23,340  26,436  14.73% 
X2: labor (persons)
Taiwan  3879  2450  3958  2507  3969  2529  4037  2657  4104  2667  1.13% 
China  2210  1699  2494  1849  2862  2041  3272  2261  3603  2389  9.78% 
f1: physical capital (USD million)
Taiwan  420  490  432  581  456  620  443  594  442  585  1.05% 
China  101  107  126  131  173  179  212  221  247  253  17.79% 
P1: price of investments (USD million/USD million)
Taiwan  0.0334  0.0551  0.0303  0.0395  0.0215  0.0169  0.0167  0.0130  0.0151  0.0090  −15.88% 
China  0.0150  0.0147  0.0151  0.0147  0.0177  0.0188  0.0162  0.0285  0.0203  0.0250  6.05% 
P2: price of loans (USD million/USD million)
Taiwan  0.0206  0.0040  0.0229  0.0042  0.0242  0.0044  0.0238  0.0042  0.0237  0.0035  2.80% 
China  0.0805  0.0137  0.1082  0.0280  0.1199  0.0364  0.1178  0.0321  0.1250  0.0324  8.80% 
W1: price of financial funds (USD million/USD million)
Taiwan  0.0057  0.0011  0.0071  0.0012  0.0077  0.0013  0.0073  0.0012  0.0076  0.0012  5.75% 
China  0.0154  0.0041  0.0255  0.0085  0.0316  0.0091  0.0317  0.0088  0.0378  0.0111  17.96% 
W2: price of labor (USD million per person)
Taiwan  0.0384  0.0098  0.0383  0.0096  0.0415  0.0093  0.0427  0.0106  0.0440  0.0113  2.71% 
China  0.0256  0.0095  0.0327  0.0119  0.0419  0.0433  0.0377  0.0109  0.0411  0.0120  9.46% 

The price of investments (p1), representing the return on investment, shows that the price of investment in Taiwan was higher than that in China in 2010, but it decreased over time at a rate of −15.88%. While such a price in China showed a low positive level of growth in 2010–2013, it was catching up with Taiwanese banks in 2014. As for the price of loans (p2), representing the return to loans, Table 2 shows that this price has been more than 4 times higher in China versus that in Taiwan during the sample period, which implies a much higher return rate for making loans in China. Such a difference in prices of outputs could induce different portfolio decisions for banks in Taiwan and China.

For input prices, the price of financial funds (w1) in Taiwan is much cheaper than that in China, whereas the price of labor (w2) in Taiwan is relatively higher than that in China. The prices of both inputs are also found to be increasing over time, and a relative higher growth rate can be seen especially in China. The difference in relative prices in inputs between Taiwan and China provides strong incentives for banks in both places to operate on the opposite side of the Taiwan Strait under the recently signed financial cooperation agreement.

In sum, the high growth of outputs in China and the difference in output structure and prices between two economies induce mutual incentives for financial cooperation. Furthermore, the vast difference in the relative price ratio and growth rate of inputs for banks in Taiwan and China may result in different impacts of price changes on bank efficiency and productivity.

Empirical resultsAnalysis of meta-profit and group-specific profit inefficienciesResults of meta-profit inefficiency and its decompositions

To consider the different production environments of banks in China and Taiwan, we employ the proposed profit metafrontier framework to compare bank performances across the Taiwan Strait. Table 3 presents the results of meta-profit inefficiency and its decompositions for Chinese and Taiwanese banking industries over the period 2010–2014. The meta-profit inefficiency (πI*) is defined as the profit difference between maximum profit and observed profit to a normalized vector, ptgyt+wtgxt (representing a bank's production size), as in Eq. (8). Table 3 indicates that the mean meta-profit inefficiency (πI*) of Taiwanese banks (0.6252) is about two times higher than that of Chinese banks (0.3059). It implies that Chinese banks are on average closer to the maximal profit benchmark than Taiwanese banks, and thus they are better in profit efficiency.

Table 3.

Meta-profit inefficiency and its decomposition.

YearChinaTaiwan
πI∗  TI∗  AI∗  πI∗  TI∗  AI∗ 
2010  0.3355    0.0871    0.2483  0.6476    0.0638    0.5838 
2011  0.3212    0.0659    0.2552  0.7458    0.0632    0.6826 
2012  0.2757    0.0665    0.2092  0.6373    0.0505    0.5868 
2013  0.2973    0.0747    0.2226  0.6259    0.0511    0.5748 
2014  0.2999    0.1019    0.1980  0.4695    0.0652    0.4042 
mean  0.3059*    0.0792*    0.2267*  0.6252*    0.0588*    0.5665* 
*

Significant difference at the 5% level between Taiwanese and Chinese banks by the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test.

Profit inefficiency consists of two components: technical inefficiency TI* and allocative inefficiency AI*. Table 3 shows that the technical inefficiency (TI*) score for banks in China and Taiwan is respectively 0.0792 and 0.0588, implying that the profit loss due to technical inefficiency is negligible compared to that from allocative inefficiencies (AI*) score, showing 0.2267 and 0.5665 for banks in China and Taiwan, respectively. Such a huge difference between allocative inefficiency and technical inefficiency has been found in each year for banks in Taiwan and China. Therefore, we may conclude that profit inefficiency can be mostly attributed to allocative inefficiency for the sample banks. In addition, the relatively high mean allocative inefficiency of banks in Taiwan as compared to that of banks in China also indicates a better allocation of output-input mix of Chinese city banks over Taiwanese banks. The differences in πI*, TI*, and AI* between Taiwanese banks and Chinese banks are found to be significantly different at the 5% level by the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test.

Results of group-specific profit inefficiency and its decompositions

For a comparison of profit inefficiency between group-specific and meta-frontier frameworks, we conduct group-specific profit inefficiency analysis. Table 4 summarizes the results of group-specific profit inefficiency and its decomposition. We find that the mean group-specific profit inefficiency (πI) is 0.1973 for Taiwanese banks and 0.2986 for Chinese banks, denoting that Taiwanese banks are a bit closer to their own Taiwan specific group profit frontier than Chinese banks to the China group specific profit frontier.

Table 4.

Group-specific profit inefficiency and its decomposition.

YearChinaTaiwan
πI  TI  AI  πI  TI  AI 
2010  0.3332    0.0608    0.2724  0.2677    0.0584    0.2093 
2011  0.3199    0.0464    0.2734  0.1907    0.0369    0.1539 
2012  0.2720    0.0478    0.2241  0.1755    0.0300    0.1455 
2013  0.2665    0.0517    0.2149  0.1846    0.0254    0.1593 
2014  0.3013    0.0852    0.2161  0.1679    0.0249    0.1430 
Mean  0.2986    0.0584    0.2402  0.1973    0.0351    0.1622 

It should be also noted that the values of profit inefficiency for Taiwanese banks estimated from group frontier (0.1973 in Table 4) and metafrontier (0.6252 in Table 3) are found to be significant different. Such discrepancy in profit inefficiency may reveal a fact that Taiwanese banks operate much better under current Taiwan specific technology than under a potential metafrontier technology, given current input and output prices. On the contrary, the difference in values of profit inefficiency for Chinese banks estimated from group frontier (0.3059 in Table 4) and metafrontier (0.2986 in Table 3) are found to be insignificant. The Chinese banks thus perform no difference in profit efficiency between under China group specific technology and under the metafrontier technology.

Allocative inefficiency (AI) shows similar pattern as that in profit inefficiency. The negligible values of technical inefficiency (TI) between banks in Taiwan and banks in China also indicate that the group-specific profit inefficiency may be mainly attributed to their allocative inefficiency.

Results of the profit inefficiency gap and its decompositions

As indicated in Eq. (10) earlier, πIhG can be regarded as the difference in DMUs’ maximum profits between operating under the metafrontier and operating under the group frontier. A higher value in πIhG implies a better potential profit increment for a bank to adopt the metafrontier technology. On the contrary, a bank with a low value in πIhG would imply there is low potential profit increment for it to undertake the metafrontier technology, but it can instead undertake the group frontier technology.

Table 5 shows that the mean profit inefficiency gap (πIG) is 0.4279 in Taiwanese banks and 0.0073 in Chinese banks. A very low gap value for the Chinese banks means that the profit gain will be negligible for Chinese banks to operate under the metafrontier technology since their gaps between group and meta-profit frontiers are very small. On the contrary, Taiwanese banks have a relatively high value (0.4279) of πIhG, which implies that Taiwanese banks can potentially increase their profit up to 43% of their production size if they operate under the metafrontier rather than under the current Taiwanese group frontier. Therefore, Taiwanese banks can reap much profit gain if they can operate using the profit metafrontier, whereas such profit gain to Chinese banks may be very small.

Table 5.

Profit inefficiency and its components’ gaps.

YearChinaTaiwan
πIG  TIG  AIG  πIG  TIG  AIG 
2010  0.0023    0.0264    -0.0241  0.3799    0.0054    0.3745 
2011  0.0013    0.0195    -0.0182  0.5550    0.0263    0.5287 
2012  0.0038    0.0187    -0.0149  0.4617    0.0204    0.4413 
2013  0.0307    0.0230    0.0077  0.4413    0.0257    0.4156 
2014  -0.0015    0.0167    -0.0181  0.3016    0.0404    0.2612 
mean  0.0073*    0.0209    -0.0135*  0.4279*    0.0236    0.4043* 
*

Significant difference at the 5% level between Taiwanese and Chinese banks by the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test.

Table 5 also shows that the allocative inefficiency gap (AIG) for Taiwanese banks (mean value=0.4043) contributes mostly to profit inefficiency (mean value=0.4279). Therefore, manager's ability of finding a better input output mix to maximize profit (given input and output prices) under metafrontier technology is crucial and the key to the profit maximization for Taiwanese banks. The Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test results on the profit inefficiency gap and the allocative inefficiency gap between Taiwanese banks and Chinese banks are significantly different at the 5% level.

Results of the metafrontier profit LPI and gap

The metafrontier profit LPI (πL*) expresses the change in profit productivity over time for banks in Taiwan and China given a common profit frontier. As in previous sections, the metafrontier profit Luenberger productivity is defined as growth, decline, and constant if πL*>0, <0, and =0, respectively. Table 6 lists the mean values of πL* for Chinese banks (−0.0645) and for the Taiwanese banks (−0.0736) during the sample period 2010–2014. We see that, given a profit metafrontier, both Chinese and Taiwanese banks have experienced profit productivity declines, and the average declining rate of profit productivity for Chinese banks is significantly lower than that of Taiwanese banks as the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test presents.

Table 6.

Group-specific profit LPI πL, metafrontier profit LPI πL* and their gap (πLG).

Year  ChinaTaiwan
  πLG  πL∗  πL  πLG  πL∗  πL 
2010-2011  0.0081     -0.0765     -0.0846  -0.184     -0.109     0.075 
2011-2012  0.0257     -0.1018     -0.1275  -0.0589     -0.0589    
2012-2013  0.0465     -0.0336     -0.0801  -0.0798     -0.0752     0.0046 
2013-2014  0.1271     -0.046     -0.1731  -0.0491     -0.0512     -0.0021 
Mean  0.0518*     -0.0645*     -0.1163  -0.093*     -0.0736*     0.0194 
*

Significant difference at the 5% level between Taiwanese and Chinese banks by the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test.

As shown in Eq. (13), the profit Luenberger productivity gap is defined as πLhG=πL*t,t+1−πLht,t+1. If πL*t,t+1<πLht,t+1, πLG<0, then a DMU's profit productivity growth between periods t and t+1 under the meta-technology is higher than that under the group-specific technology. The negative value of πLG implies a convergence of the profit group-specific frontier toward the profit metafrontier. Thus, (πLG) can be regarded as the catch-up index. Having consecutive negative (πLG) values, a DMU's profit group frontier catches up with the profit metafrontier over time, which implies that the DMUs in such a group have better ability to reap the benefit of adopting the meta-profit frontier. On the contrary, the positive value of πLG implies a divergence of the profit group-specific frontier from the profit meta frontier. The profit productivity growth rate from the group frontier is however lower than that from the metafrontier.

Table 6 summarizes the results of the profit LPI gap (πLG). The mean values of the profit productivity gaps (πLG) are 0.0518 for Chinese banks and −0.0930 for Taiwanese banks. The positive values of πLG for Chinese banks denote divergence in their productivity along the China profit frontier over time, while the Taiwanese banks with negative values of πLG show their productivity growth is catching up with the meta-profit frontier over time.

Overall, the results present an opposite pattern of productivity growth for Taiwanese and Chinese banks.

Conclusion

To accommodate the potential measuring problem of the ratio-based MPI which fails to model the distance function with both input contraction and output expansion, Chambers et al. (1996) develop the difference-based LPI with a directional distance function. Despite LPI having received much attention with various applications, previous research on LPI still fails to insure a proper and meaningful productivity assessment for DMUs with different production technology. In this paper we thus adopt the metafrontier framework of Battese et al. (2004) and O’Donnell et al. (2008) and extend the profit-oriented LPI of Juo et al. (2015) from a group-specific frontier to a metafrontier version. The proposed model helps us to measure the profit productivity and efficiency performances across banks in Taiwan and China, which are operating under different production technologies. We also examine the degree of convergence between the profit group frontier and profit metafrontier by comparing those profit LPI results from the group specific and metafrontier technologies for Taiwanese and Chinese city banks.

The empirical evidence herein finds that relative to Taiwanese banks, Chinese banks are characterized as having higher profit efficiency and higher allocative efficiency under meta-technology. Allocative inefficiency plays a major contribution to profit inefficiency. Given a smaller profit inefficiency gap for Chinese banks than that for Taiwanese banks, we conclude that the Chinese banks have better technology in profit creation than Taiwanese banks during the sample period. However, Taiwanese banks may reap much profit gain if they can reach the profit metafrontier, whereas such profit gains for Chinese banks may be very small. Therefore, the Taiwan government should promote Taiwanese banks to take advantage of the financial cooperation between Taiwan and China.

The results of the profit metafrontier LPI analysis show that both Chinese and Taiwanese banks have experienced declines in profit productivity. However, results of different patterns in profit productivity dynamics also indicate a divergence in productivity growth for Chinese city banks and a convergent productivity growth for Taiwanese banks.

References
[Chambers et al., 1996]
R.G. Chambers, R. Färe, S. Grosskopf.
Productivity growth in APEC countries.
Pacific Econ. Rev., 1 (1996), pp. 181-190
[Briec and Kerstens, 2009]
W. Briec, K. Kerstens.
The Luenberger productivity indicator: an economic specification leading to infeasibilities.
Econ. Model., 26 (2009), pp. 597-600
[Epure et al., 2010]
M. Epure, K. Kerstens, P. Diego.
Bank productivity and performance groups: a decomposition approach based upon the Luenberger productivity indicator.
Eur. J. Oper. Res., 154 (2010), pp. 396-409
[Lansink et al., 2015]
A.O. Lansink, S. Stefanou, T. Serra.
Primal and dual dynamic Luenberger productivity indicators.
Eur. J. Oper. Res., 241 (2015), pp. 555-563
[Lin et al., 2017]
Y.H. Lin, T.T. Fu, C.L. Chen.
Non-radial cost Luenberger productivity indicator.
Eur. J. Oper. Res., 256 (2017), pp. 629-639
[Juo et al., 2015]
J.C. Juo, T.T. Fu, M.M. Yu.
Profit-oriented productivity change.
Omega, 57 (2015), pp. 176-187
[Boussemart et al., 2018]
J.P. Boussemart, G.D. Ferrier, H. Leleu, Z. Shen.
An expanded decomposition of the Luenberger productivity indicator with an application to the Chinese healthcare sector.
[O’Donnell et al., 2008]
C.J. O’Donnell, D.S.P. Rao, G.E. Battese.
Meta-frontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology gaps.
Empir. Econ., 34 (2008), pp. 231-255
[Battese et al., 2004]
G.E. Battese, D.S.P. Rao, C.J. O’Donnell.
A meta-frontier production function for estimation of technical efficiencies and technology gaps for firms operating under different technologies.
J. Prod. Anal., 21 (2004), pp. 91-103
[Chen et al., 2009]
K.H. Chen, Y.J. Huang, C.H. Yang.
Analysis of regional productivity growth in china: a generalized metafrontier MPI approach.
China Econ. Rev., 20 (2009), pp. 777-792
[Oh, 2010]
D.-h. Oh.
A metafrontier approach for measuring an environmentally sensitive productivity growth index.
Energy Econ., 32 (2010), pp. 146-157
[Oh and Lee, 2010]
D. Oh, J. Lee.
A metafrontier approach for measuring Malmquist productivity index.
Empir. Econ., 38 (2010), pp. 47-64
[Chen and Yang, 2011]
K.H. Chen, H.Y. Yang.
A cross-country comparison of productivity growth using the generalised metafrontier Malmquist productivity index: with application to banking industries in Taiwan and China.
J. Prod. Anal., 35 (2011), pp. 197-212
[Huang and Fu, 2013]
M.Y. Huang, T.T. Fu.
An examination of the cost efficiency of banks in Taiwan and China using the metafrontier cost function.
J. Prod. Anal., 40 (2013), pp. 387-406
[Huang et al., 2015]
M.Y. Huang, J.C. Juo, T.T. Fu.
Metafrontier cost Malmquist productivity index: an application to Taiwanese and Chinese commercial banks.
J. Prod. Anal., 44 (2015), pp. 321-335
[Mulwa and Emrouznejad, 2013]
R. Mulwa, A. Emrouznejad.
Measuring productive efficiency using Nerlovian profit efficiency indicator and metafrontier analysis.
Oper. Res., 13 (2013), pp. 271-287
[Fu et al., 2016]
T.T. Fu, J.C. Juo, H.C. Chiang.
Risk-based decompositions of the meta profit efficiency of Taiwanese and Chinese banks.
Omega, 62 (2016), pp. 34-46
[Balk, 2018]
B.M. Balk.
Profit-oriented productivity change: a comment.
Omega, 78 (2018), pp. 176-178
[Aparicio et al., 2012]
J. Aparicio, J.T. Pastor, S.C. Ray.
An Overall Measure of Technical Inefficiency at the Firm and at the Industrial Level: The ‘Lost Return on the Dollar’ Revisited. Working Paper.
(2012),
(No.-02)
[Chambers et al., 1998]
R.G. Chambers, Y. Chung, R. Färe.
Profit directional distance functions and Nerlovian efficiency.
J. Opt. Theory Appl., 98 (1998), pp. 351-364
[Berger and Humphrey, 1997]
A.N. Berger, D.B. Humphrey.
Efficiency of financial institutions: international survey and directions for future research.
Eur. J. Oper. Res., 98 (1997), pp. 175-212

Given a time-invariant direction vector g, the profit Luenberger productivity indicator (πLt,t+1) is an empirical Bennet quantity indicator. Under our time-variant direction vector setting, πLt,t+1 is not equal to the Bennet quantity indicator. We thank a referee for raising the problem of the time-invariant direction vector.

The LPI decomposition and its empirical implementation are available upon request.

Copyright © 2019. ACEDE
Article options
Tools