covid
Buscar en
Contaduría y Administración
Toda la web
Inicio Contaduría y Administración Complex stylized facts of the Mexican economy: a hirschmanian perspective (to at...
Información de la revista
Vol. 60. Núm. 2.
Páginas 291-325 (abril - junio 2015)
Compartir
Compartir
Descargar PDF
Más opciones de artículo
Visitas
2544
Vol. 60. Núm. 2.
Páginas 291-325 (abril - junio 2015)
Open Access
Complex stylized facts of the Mexican economy: a hirschmanian perspective (to attack the “fear of growing”, more and better)
Hechos estilizados complejos de la economía mexicana: una perspectiva hirschmaniana (para combatir el “miedo a crecer”, más y mejor)
Visitas
2544
Carlos Guerrero de Lizardi
Autor para correspondencia
cguerrero@economia.unam.mx

The author wishes to thank two anonymous referees for their valuable comments.
Facultad de Economía, Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México
Este artículo ha recibido

Under a Creative Commons license
Información del artículo
Resumen
Texto completo
Bibliografía
Descargar PDF
Estadísticas
Figuras (18)
Mostrar másMostrar menos
Tablas (14)
Table 1. Growth rate of CPI components by producer sector, 2008-2013, monthly data.
Table 2. Growth rate of CPI components by producer sector, and economic growth rate, 2008-2013, monthly data.
Table 3. Investment ratios and growth rates of GDP, 1960-2012.
Table 4. Direct and indirect linkages in the Mexican economy and Manufacturing sector, internal matrices, Mexican pesos, 1993, 2003 and 2008.
Table 5. Direct and indirect linkages in the Mexican economy and Manufacturing sector, internal matrices, ratios, 1993, 2003 and 2008.
Table 6. Direct and indirect linkages, Mexican economy and manufacturing sector, total economy matrices, Mexican pesos, 1993 and 2003.
Table 7. Direct and indirect linkages, Mexican economy and manufacturing sector, total economy matrices, ratios, 1993 and 2003.
Table 1A Sectors of the Mexican Economy.
Table 2A Correlation coefficients between sectors, in levels.
Table 3A Correlation coefficients between sectors, in growth rates.
Table 4A Granger causality test, inflation and economic growth.
Table 5A Granger causality test, current account as % of GDP and economic growth.
Table 6A Granger causality test, investment ratio and economic growth.
Table 7A Database.
Mostrar másMostrar menos
Abstract

We elaborate some complex stylized facts related to the Mexican economy. The analyzed period runs from 1960 to 2013 with selected subperiods. Our main findings are: 1) there are involuntary idle capacities in the manufacturing industries; 2) the growth of the Mexican economy is not balanced but unbalanced; 3) there is an inflation-free environment. This fact is consistent with the previous ones; 4) there is a mixed of efficient and inefficient sequences of investment; 5) the stimulus of manufacturing exports on macroeconomic performance has been offset by its imports; 6) the deficits in manufacturing balance and in the current account have been financed without difficulty. Of course, this financing capacity constitutes a second best condition; 7) according to a backward linkages analysis, the towing capacity of manufacturing sector over the Mexican economy would be a larger one if the manufacturing imports penetration had not been so intense since the trade liberalization; and 8) the size of the positive effect of the manufacturing sector on the economy and on the non-manufacturing sectors diminished since the early eighties. Our complex stylized facts highlight the need for an upgrading of the current economic policies.

Keywords:
Complex stylized facts
Albert O. Hirschman
Mexican economy
Resumen

Elaboramos algunos hechos estilizados complejos relacionados con la economía mexicana. El período analizado se extiende desde 1960 hasta 2013, con subperiodos seleccionados. Nuestras principales conclusiones son las siguientes: 1) existen capacidades ociosas involuntarias en las industrias manufactureras; 2) el crecimiento de la economía mexicana no es balanceado sino desbalanceado; 3) existe un entorno macroeconómico libre de inflación. Este hecho es coherente con los anteriores; 4) se observa una secuencia de inversiones eficientes e ineficientes; 5) el estímulo de las exportaciones manufactureras hacia la economía en su conjunto ha sido parcialmente anulado por sus importaciones; 6) los déficits en la balanza manufacturera y en la cuenta corriente se han financiado sin dificultad. Sobra decir que esta capacidad de financiamiento constituye una segunda mejor opción; 7) de acuerdo con un análisis de encadenamientos hacia atrás, la capacidad de arrastre del sector manufacturero hacia la economía sería mayor si la penetración de las importaciones no hubiera sido tan intensa desde la liberalización del comercio; y 8) el efecto positivo del sector manufacturero en la economía y en los sectores no manufactureros ha disminuido desde principios de los años ochenta. Los hechos propuestos revelan la necesidad de mejorar las políticas económicas aplicadas actualmente.

Palabras clave:
Hechos estilizados complejos
Albert O. Hirschman
Economía mexicana
Texto completo
Introduction

“It is useful from time to time to revisit the pioneers in a field. The richness of their original thought is often diminished as new specialists in a field are educated or, rather, trained. Stylized caricatures and toy models out-compete nuanced multidisciplinary narratives in the competition for shelf-space in textbooks. After the students ingest the textbooks and go forth in the discipline as properly trained specialists, they are hard put just to keep up with the latest publications and to do their own bit to push the frontier forward. Outside of those inclined to intellectual history, the specialists have little occasion to go back to revisit the pioneers.” David Ellerman (2004:311)

Extending the seminal idea proposed by Kaldor (1961), we elaborate some complex stylized facts related to the Mexican economy. The analyzed period runs from 1960 to 2013 with selected subperiods. By the way, the word complex merely recognizes the fact that the functioning of an economy in a globalized world full of innovations and in a heterogeneous society as the Mexican is a challenge that economic policy makers and the private sector have to face in order to accomplish their goals.a We hope that our complex stylized facts express to some extent these circumstances.b

Although the stylized facts gathered by Kaldor allegedly sought to be theoretically neutral, our complex stylized facts are inspired in a book, among others, entitled The Strategy of Economic Development written by Albert O. Hirschman (1915-2012) long ago. Other sources of inspiration are Keynes (1936), Kalecki (López & Assous, 2010), Steindl (1976), and Kaldor (1966 and 1967).

Our complex stylized facts tackle relevant characteristics of the Mexican economy. Among others, we analyze some properties of its macroeconomic stability in terms of the convergence of the actual output to its potential, and in terms of the balanced or unbalanced growth of the economy as a whole and its parts. Thereon, the availability of involuntary idle productive capacity in the nineties and in the first decades of this century, and the unbalanced growth all through the analyzed period, are complex stylized facts of the Mexican economy. In the present, both facts are advantages. Some examples are the following.

First example, from a microeconomic perspective a significant margin of spare capacity within companies implies that, in a case of increased demand, firms would be able to increase production without pushing its costs, meaning that the economy could grow faster without generating inflationary pressure. Second, from a macroeconomic perspective under a condition of not complete use of physical capital, a responsible deficit is not a risk to macroeconomic stability. On the contrary, represents a policy instrument to narrow the gap between both economic activity levels, which by the way would generate positive effects in the short term and long term, among others a boost in investment. Third example, to move from an economy with certain characteristics to another superior one, the current productive structure has to be altered.

The existence of an inflation-free environment constitutes another complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy. This fact is consistent with the previous ones. Some of the evidence is the following. By no means the variations in prices are neither widespread nor sustained in the Mexican economy between 2008 and 2013. It seems that the positive and negative variations in prices obey to rather idiosyncratic conditions by producer sector, instead of responding to a generalized situation determine by a presumable disequilibrium between aggregated supply and demand, or by an outstanding macroeconomic performance.

The mixed of efficient and inefficient sequences of investment constitute another complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy. Therefore, it seems feasible to reach an adequate economic growth rate without the need to substantially increase the investment ratios, or equivalently, the internal and external funding. Some of the facts are the following. First, it is patent the relationship between investment ratios (GFCF/GDP for example) and economic growth all through the analyzed period. Second, the range of investment ratios is particularly narrow, considering the wide range of economic growth rates. Historically speaking, an economic growth rate proximate to 5 is linked with numerous investment ratios. Third, there is not a consistent match between the values of the ratios and the economic growth rates if we order all them from highest to lowest. And fourth, the macroeconomic returns of the investment efforts are not the same during the analyzed period, that is to say, there is a diminishing impact of investment on economic growth.

From 1960 to 2012 the share of the manufacturing as a percentage of the GDP ranged slightly from 15% to 20%. In the 60's and 70's, there is a trend with a negative slope in the share, but since 1981 there is a positive one. Even so, the size of the positive effect of the manufacturing sector on the economy and the non-manufacturing sectors, that is the elasticity, has diminished during the analyzed period. The above constitutes another complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy. To support our claim, we analyze the external balance of manufacturing with a slightly global value chains emphasis, and its backward linkages using three official input-output matrices.

Before starting, we want to explicit our intentions. Bearing in mind Kaldor (1961), we hope that our complex stylized facts serve to the economist community to agree on the main features of the Mexican economy. Of course, the next step would be its joint explanation. As will be justified in the final reflections, our complex stylized facts highlight the need for an upgrading of the current economic policies. In this sense, to attack the “fear of growing” more and better, that suffer the economic policy makers in Mexico, among many others countries, one of the mantras proposed reads as follows, “grow, grow and grow”.c

Actual and potential output

An outstanding characteristic of the Mexican economy is its macroeconomic stability. Basically, it is the result of economic policies and institutional reforms that have been implemented since the debt crisis at the beginning of the eighties. In this sense, the transformation of the Mexican economy should be understood as a nonstop process. Among the alternatives to illustrate this feature, a favorite one has been to establish the convergence of the actual output to its potential (see for example Carstens, 2013b:10), using a smoothing tool known as Hodrick-Prescott filter.d The presumption of a balanced growth, as appears in Fig 1, is a consequence of this tradition.

Fig. 1.

Actual and potential output, 1993-2013, monthly data.

(0,17MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

The reference to the Hodrick-Prescott filter and other ones, with and without corrections, is a common place in the applied literature. In an attempt to avoid the boundaries of the HP filter and of the modeling of a production function, in the so-called Criterios Generales de Política Económica 2014 (Presidencia de la República, 2013:76) the potential output was established as an average of economic growth rates registered during a “relatively long period”. However, following the same tradition of the contemporary macroeconomics, according to this “simple and transparent” exercise of smoothing, the economy regularly operates under complete use of its physical capital.

If we use the same mathematical definition of potential output into a broader period, then we could easily establish the same characteristic of the Mexican economy as appears in the next figure (Fig. 2).

Fig. 2.

Actual and potential output, 1929-2012, annual data.

(0,05MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

A visible limit of this tradition is that the potential output, theoretically defined as the output level associated with the efficient and full employment of productive resources in an economy, is a non-observable variable, which means that its measurement, being optimistically, is full of obstacles.e It is worthwhile to remark that the quantification of physical capital and labor into a single economic unit is a difficult task. Suffice to say that systematically economic units do not value its physical capital correctly, and there is a severe deficiency in terms of aggregate volume measurements cause by the unavailability of individual price indexes and by the not fully quality adjustment of the aggregate ones (Guerrero, 2009 and 2013).f By the way, the evolution of hours worked in time is another challenge in terms of its quality adjustment.g

The hearth of the matter is that the statement about the convergence of the actual GDP to its potential is rather theoretical, specifically it constitutes an assumption, and by the way a distinguishing one.h Therefore, we think it is a debatable position. In first place, there is not a correspondence between the theoretical definition and its practical measurement. In second place, from an alternative tradition it has been argued that market economies do not generate, automatically, enough aggregate demand in order to match actual and potential output. In this sense, the equalization of the levels of economic activity is a rare episode, and there are not repeated sequences of recessionary gaps and inflationary gaps as are conceptualized by this tradition. There is only one aggregated supply curve, which does not distinguish the short term and the long term, with a vertical portion at the end of it.

The degree of use of installed capacity is a key variable in order to evaluate the magnitude of the convergence of actual output to its potential, and to understand the investment decisions (Steindl, 1952).i The following scatter plot shows the degree of use as a percentage and the growth rate of real output in manufacturing, between 1994 and 2013 (Fig. 3).

Fig. 3.

Degree of use of installed capacity and growth rate of real output in manufacturing, 1994-2013, monthly data.

(0,09MB).
Source: own calculations using data from Monthly Surveys of Manufacturing Industries, CMAP and EMIM, INEGI.

As expected, there is a positive relationship between growth rate of real output and the percentage of use of installed capacity. Throughout the analyzed period, the range of use of physical capital in the manufacturing was between 74 and 86 percent. It is fascinating and invites speculation to note that, in the first panel, a range between 80 and 82 of use of physical capital is linked with a cloud of growth rates that range from –5% to 18%, by the way the maximum value during the analyzed period. Something similar can be said about the second panel. Regardless of the month and year, the Figure 4 shows the maximum values of the degree of use of installed capacity reported by sector.

Fig. 4.

Maximum degree of use of installed capacity, manufacturing sectors, 1994-2013, monthly data.

(0,11MB).
Source: own calculations using data from Monthly Surveys of Manufacturing Industries, CMAP and EMIM INEGI.

All through the analyzed period, it seems that there are involuntary idle capacities in both, individual activities and in the manufacturing as a whole. The above constitutes a complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy, which is opposed to the previous tradition that determines potential output by means of a growth component. In the same direction, using a Kaleckian background, Guerrero (2012) estimated that if the manufacturing sectors had fully utilized its production capacity between 2003 and 2008, the average rate of growth of the Mexican economy would have been 6.81% and not 3.36%. As is well known two caveats to our interpretation are the following. The first one, the idle capacity, technically speaking, is necessary. The second one, the idle capacity may not be competitive at the time by market conditions. Although the gap between growth rates proposed by Guerrero (2012) may sound excessive, it simply constitutes a reference point regarding the latent capabilities of the Mexican economy in the short run.

As was noted at the beginning of this section, one implication of the first perspective revised is that the dynamic of the economy is a balanced one, whatever that means. Nonetheless, according to Hirschman (1959:51-2) the favourable case is the unbalanced path in the following contextj:

“In this version the requirement of balanced growth is derived from the demand side. It is argued that a new venture –say, a shoe factory– which gets underway by itself in an underdeveloped country is likely to turn into a failure: the workers, employees, and owners of the shoe factory will obviously not buy all its output, while the other citizens of the country are caught in an “underdevelopment equilibrium” where they are just able jointly to afford their own meager output. Therefore, it is argued, to make development possible it is necessary to start, at one and the same time, a large number of new industries which will be each others’ clients through the purchases of their workers, employees, and owners. For this reason, the theory has now been annexed to the ‘theory of the big push’. A big push could, of course, result from one or a few big projects, or from a large number of projects of varying size that dovetail with one another. It is clearly the latter alternative of the ‘big push’ theory that is implied by the theory of balanced growth… My principal point is that the theory fails as a theory of development. Development presumably means the process of change of one type of economy into some other more advanced type. But such a process is given up as hopeless by the balanced growth theory which finds it difficult to visualize how the ‘underdevelopment equilibrium’ can be broken into at any one point.”

As a first step to explore the unbalanced hypothesis, the following scatter plot shows the Mexican economy disaggregated by thirteen sectors from 1993 to 2012 with annual frequency (Fig. 5).k

Fig. 5.

Mexican economy disaggregated by thirteen sectors, in levels (2008=100), 1993-2012, annual data.

(0,2MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

Broadly speaking, there are co-movements between the levels of economic activity by sectors, more clearly in some cases than in others. In the case of sectors 12 and 13, that is, “Accommodation and food services”, and “Legislative, justice, etc.” definitely that is not the case. The figure allows us to find out some nonlinear relationships between the analyzed variables (Fig. 6). The next scatter-plot shows the variables in growth rates.

Fig. 6.

Growth rates in percentage, thirteen sectors, 1994-2012, annual data.

(0,19MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

It seems that the balanced growth hypothesis is not supported by the information content in the figures; in other words, there is evidence in favor of the Hirschmanian hypothesis in the case of the Mexican economy during the analyzed period.

We want to close this section with two observations. The first one, the determination of potential output in an economy strongly linked with the rest of the world should be upgraded in the sense of taking into account not only the domestic productive resources but also, to some extent, the external ones. In order to measure this broad definition of potential output, one concept that should be explicit is the so-called sustainable imports level. The second one, the hypothesis about the balanced or unbalanced growth in a globalized economy is a subordinated one. The heart of the matter is rather if the economies have, for example, a sustainable current account. Later we will continue analyzing this concern.

Inflation

Inflation is a summary measure of variations in prices of goods and services consumed by households. From an aggregate point of view, to some extent, it reveals the disequilibrium between aggregated supply and demand. In this sense, in the Appendix we show the results of Granger causality tests from one lag to twelve (monthly data) between 2008 and 2013. In all cases, the causality runs exclusively from the economic growth rate to inflation –that makes sense.

According to an orthodox macroeconomic point of view, inflation refers, strictly, to the widespread and sustained increase in prices over time. Based on the Mexican consumer price index, the following figure (Fig. 7) shows the general inflation and the core one. The starting point was selected considering the current monetary policy framework.

Fig. 7.

General and core inflation, 2008-2013, monthly data.

(0,06MB).
Source: own calculations using data from INEGI.

Let us begin with a truism, the negative slopes point out that there is not a sustained increase in prices over time, at least in the analyzed period. Among other factors, the competitive environment created by the open economy has played a positive role. Certainly, the inflation-targeting regime has been effective as a nominal anchor of the economy. Since then, the set of actions taken by the Mexican Central Bank has been, evidently, one key of the success. Its handling of expectation, for example, has been formidable. The question of the role played by the nominal exchange rate, or other nominal price, for example the minimum wage, exceeds the purpose of this document.

The following table (Table 1) shows statistics by every one of the producer sector of the goods and services included in the CPI. As the gentle reader will notice, the disaggregated analysis will help us to understand differently the relationship between the dynamics of prices and economic activities.

Table 1.

Growth rate of CPI components by producer sector, 2008-2013, monthly data.

  Median  Mean  Std. Dev.  Ratio  Max  Min  Gap 
Agriculture, livestock and fishing  6.82  6.67  6.97  1.04  24.79  -7.74  32.52 
Food, beverages and cigarettes  7.02  6.71  1.90  0.28  10.51  3.30  7.21 
Textiles, clothing and leather  2.88  2.65  0.68  0.26  3.56  0.98  2.58 
Wood products  2.84  2.94  1.55  0.53  5.88  -0.63  6.51 
Paper products, printing and publishing  4.21  3.89  1.89  0.49  6.76  -1.20  7.96 
Chemicals, petroleum, rubber and plastic  6.07  5.90  1.54  0.26  8.33  3.02  5.31 
Non-metallic mineral products  5.69  5.74  2.51  0.44  10.47  0.25  10.22 
Metal products, machinery and equipment  2.23  2.54  1.79  0.71  6.90  0.18  6.72 
Other manufacturing  4.12  4.59  1.63  0.35  8.14  1.93  6.21 
Electricity  4.14  3.24  4.67  1.44  10.87  -5.43  16.31 
Retail trade, restaurants and hotels  4.81  5.02  0.80  0.16  7.39  3.91  3.48 
Transport and communications  1.63  1.47  3.33  2.26  6.48  -8.45  14.93 
Finance, insurance and real estate  2.65  2.90  0.83  0.29  4.77  1.97  2.81 
Community, social and personal services  4.17  4.00  0.68  0.17  4.98  2.97  2.01 
Source: own calculations using data from INEGI.

It is worth emphasizing at least the following. First, if we compare medians or means, or maximum and minimum values, or gaps, or ratios calculated using means and standard deviations, between sectors, there is not an indiscriminate increase in prices during the analyzed period. Just a few examples. Five of the 14 sectors reported inflation lower than 3%. Only three sectors shown variability in terms of its ratio, that is to say, greater than one. And the difference between maximum and minimum values show quite heterogeneity in terms of the response between sectors, that evidently share the same general condition of the economy. The following table (Table 2) shows the maximum and minimum by date, and its corresponding observed economic growth rate based on the Global Economic Activity Indicator.

Table 2.

Growth rate of CPI components by producer sector, and economic growth rate, 2008-2013, monthly data.

  Max  DGEAI  Min  DGEAI 
Agriculture, livestock and fishing  2013/04  4.54  2012/04  4.92 
Food, beverages and cigarettes  2009/02  -9.66  2010/10  4.23 
Textiles, clothing and leather  2011/12  3.72  2008/01  3.33 
Wood products  2012/09  1.14  2013/07  NA 
Paper products, printing and publishing  2009/04  -11.52  2011/10  4.20 
Chemicals, petroleum, rubber and plastic  2012/11  3.92  2010/06  6.69 
Non-metallic mineral products  2009/03  -4.08  2012/10  4.34 
Metal products, machinery and equipment  2010/01  2.50  2011/06  3.48 
Other manufacturing  2009/09  -4.56  2011/11  4.30 
Electricity  2008/09  1.90  2013/07  NA 
Retail trade, restaurants and hotels  2008/12  -1.63  2009/11  -1.69 
Transport and communications  2010/07  4.26  2012/12  1.42 
Finance, insurance and real estate  2008/11  -1.80  2012/05  4.60 
Community, social and personal services  2009/04  -11.52  2011/09  5.02 
Source: own calculations using data from INEGI.

The extreme values do not shared dates, not even in the case of maximum values, much less in the case of minimums; and there are maximum values in condition of negative economic growth rates, and vice versa! As a matter of fact only in the case of one minimum value, related to “Retail trade, restaurants and hotels”, the observed growth rate of the Global Economic Activity Indicator was negative.

By no means variations in prices are neither widespread nor sustained in the Mexican economy from 2008 to date. It seems that the positive and negative variations in prices obey to rather idiosyncratic conditions by producer sector, instead of responding to a generalized situation determine by a presumable disequilibrium between aggregated supply and demand, or by an outstanding macroeconomic performance –what indeed constitutes a ruthless tale if we remember that between 2008 and 2013 the Mexican economy grew at an average annual rate of 1.84%, pretty far from its potential growth rate figure. Therefore, the existence of an inflation-free environment constitutes a complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy.

Last but not least, another argument, which goes beyond the purposes of this document, is linked with the fact that, frequently, official prices indexes do not completely adjust for changes in quality (Guerrero, 2008a). Notably, disregarding improves in quality leads to an overstatement of price changes and to an underestimation of economic growth (Guerrero, 2008b; Schreyer, 1996 and 1998).

We want to end this section noting the following. In first place, it is better to make a distinction between the theoretical definition of inflation and its measurement, inspired by the Mexican Central Bank's objective. In this sense, arithmetically speaking, a positive variation in the consumer price index is called inflation, and ceteris paribus, it affects the stability of the domestic currency's purchasing power, or put it correctly, the purchasing power of people.

In second place, in essence the inflation reflects always and everywhere a distributional conflict. In modern words, inflation reflects the dispute over the value added by economic agents, internal and external, which becomes visible by means of variations of nominal prices, that is, profits, wages, taxes, and the exchange rate. The most feared situation, when a government runs a deficit financed by printing money or financed with tax increases, all that is manifesting is a bargain to increase its share in the value added, at the expense of other players. From this perspective, the Mexican Central Bank's real success has been the containment of the dispute between the agents. Certainly, self-restraint of the claims of economic agents has contributed to generate an inflation-free environment.

In third place, inflation constitutes a permanent risk for economies, which simply reveals the insistence of agents with market power to increase their slice of the pie. Policy makers should combat attempts of this kind of abuse.

Investment

The investment determines what is produced and, to some extent, what is exported. According to Albert O. Hirschman, the “investment choices” constitutes the crucial problem in the development theory and policy, and the problem in our economies is, precisely, the shortage of “ability to invest”. It is interesting to note that, for our guru, the issue relating to the funding of investment is, relatively, secondary. We show some investment ratios and economic growth rates next (Fig. 8; emsp Table 3).

Fig. 8.

Investment ratios as a percentage of GDP and growth rates of GDP, 1960-2012, annual data.

(0,08MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.
Table 3.

Investment ratios and growth rates of GDP, 1960-2012.

  GFCF/GDP  Buildings/GDP  Machinery/GDP  DGDP 
Average  19.7  11.6  8.1  4.01 
Std. Deviation  2.3  1.6  1.6  3.67 
Variability coefficient  0.12  0.14  0.20  0.92 
1965-1970  19.7  12.3  7.4  6.24 
1971-1976  21.5  13.0  8.5  6.40 
1977-1982  22.9  13.5  9.3  7.13 
1983-1988  16.8  10.8  6.0  1.08 
1989-1994  19.1  10.3  8.8  3.18 
1995-2000  18.2  9.1  9.1  5.45 
2001-2006  19.9  11.5  8.4  2.90 
2007-2012  21.8  13.2  8.6  1.58 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

One interpretation of the above statistical information is the following. In first place, it is patent the association between investment ratios and economic growth in averages. To complement this, in the Appendix we show the results of Granger causality test between the investment ratios and the economic growth. As expected, according to this statistical exercise the causality runs in both directions, from ratios to growth and vice versa. In second, the range of investment ratios is particularly narrow, considering the wide range of economic growth rates. As is shown in the Figure 8 an economic growth rate proximate to 5 is linked with numerous investment ratios. In third, there is not a consistent match between the values of the ratios and the economic average growth rates if we order all them from highest to lowest. The two worst examples are the following. In 2007-2012 the investment ratios were highest than the ones reported in 2001-2006, but the economic growth rate was almost the double in 2001-2006 with respect to 2007-2012. From the hand of the second highest GFCF/GDP ratio, the economic growth rate ranked the second last place during 2007-2012, just above the worst rate registered in 1983-1988. In fourth place, the macroeconomic returns of the investment efforts are not the same during the analyzed period, that is to say, there is a diminishing impact of investment on economic growth.

As a mechanism to further explore our hypotheses derived from the contents of the above figure and table, we applied a time varying approximation with the purpose of examine the changing effect of the Gross Fixed Capital Formation (GFCF) ratio on the economy growth rate. In the observation equation (1) the elasticity is specified as a time-varying coefficient, and in the state equation (2) as a first order autoregressive process:

The system of equations were estimated using a forecast recursive algorithm known as Kalman filter. The next figure shows our statistical results (Fig. 9).

Fig. 9.

Impact of the GFCF ratio on the economic growth rate, 1960-2012.

(0,05MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

The contents of the graph suggests that the impact of the Gross Fixed Capital Formation ratio on the rate of economic growth is changing in time, in some years is positive and in others is negative, the elasticity range is wide, from 0.6 to –0.5, and that its trend is slightly negative. In short, it seems that the mixed of efficient and inefficient sequences of investments constitute a complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy. Being optimistic, it constitutes an opportunity because it seems feasible to reach an adequate economic growth rate without the need to substantially increase the investment ratios, or equivalently, the internal and external funding. Again, this statement is also opposed to Shiau, Kilpatrick, and Matthews (2002), among many others.

About the role of manufacturing in the Mexican economy

According to Kaldor (1966 and 1967) manufacturing has characteristics that make it the engine of economic growth. For dimensioning the size of the manufacturing, the following figure (Fig. 10). depicts its weight as a percentage of the Mexican economy:

Fig. 10.

The manufacturing as a percentage of the overall economy, 1921-2012, annual data.

(0,05MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

Between 1960 and 2012, the share of the manufacturing in the economy ranged from 15 to 20 percent. By the way, in The Atlas of Economic Complexity (Hausmann et al., 2011), Mexican economy ranked in the number 20, above, among others, Spain (28), China (29), Canada (41), Costa Rica (49), and Brazil (52).l This remarkable ranking speaks of the outstanding capabilities of the Mexican economy and its manufacturing sector. As another way to illustrate the strong link between the manufacturing and the economy as a whole, the following figure depicts its growth rates (Fig. 11).

Fig. 11.

Growth rates, manufacturing sector and overall economy, 1960-2012, annual data.

(0,08MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

We estimated a VAR model in order to analyze the relationship between the manufacturing and the economy as a whole. We use three lags based on lag length tests (see the Appendix). The functional form was the common one, namely, the log-log. We also applied a set of tests to verify the no-autocorrelation, the normality, the no-heteroskedasticity, weak exogeneity, and the stability condition of the VAR. According to Johansen tests (without intercept or trend), there is a long run co-movement between the levels of the variables. The elasticity rose to 1.10.

Clearly, the lineal approach is a limited one, so we applied a time varying approximation with the purpose of examine the changing effect of the manufacturing on the overall economy and on the non-manufacturing sectors. In the observation equations (3) and (5), the elasticities are specified as time-varying coefficients, and in the state equation (4) and (6) as first order autoregressive processes:

The systems of equations were estimated using a forecast recursive algorithm known as Kalman filter. The next figure (Fig. 12) shows our results.

Fig. 12.

Impact of the manufacturing on Mexican economy, 1960-2012.

(0,07MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

The figure 12 is fascinating and invites speculation. Suffice to say that the size of the positive effect of the manufacturing sector on the economy and on the non-manufacturing sectors has diminished during the analyzed period. The above constitutes another complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy.

Perhaps the reader shares the following questions. How not to think that our proposed stylized fact simply reflects the fact that the growths of manufacturing, of non-manufacturing sectors and of the economy as a whole were different? How to reconcile our proposed stylized fact with the statistical fact according to which the share of the manufacturing in the economy has been relatively stable? Two routes to answer the questions are the following. The first one points to the external balance of manufacturing with a slightly global value chains emphasis, and the second one to the manufacturing backward linkages. We will follow both directions next.

Current account

Bearing in mind an external-constrained growth model, figure 13 shows a scatter plot of the current account and the economic growth rate, and the current account as a percentage of GDP.

Fig. 13.

Current account and growth rate of GDP, millions of dollars and percentage, 1960-2012, annual data.

(0,09MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the Balanced of Payments, Mexican Central Bank, and the National Accounts System, INEGI.

Only from 1983 to 1985 and in 1987, the current account was positive. Most of the points are located in the quadrant corresponding to a deficit in the current account and a positive economic growth rate. Therefore, the current account as a percentage of GDP has been negative in most of the years. Figure 14 shows the merchandise and the manufacturing balances during the analyzed period.

Fig. 14.

Merchandise and manufacturing balances, millions of dollars, 1960-2012, annual data.

(0,06MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the Balanced of Payments, Mexican Central Bank.

We require two steps in order to formulate a reasonable interpretation of the empirical evidence. First step. From a macroeconomic point of view, it would be better to have a zero balance or a surplus in manufacturing instead of a permanent deficit, in the sense that the stimulus of manufacturing exports flies away to other countries in the form of manufacturing imports. In other words, the stimulus of manufacturing exports on macroeconomic performance and on total employment is offset by the manufacturing imports.m

The above is useful to explain the diminished impact of the manufacturing sector in the economy.

In terms of the export performance of countries within Global Value Chains, the evidence is the following.n It is necessary to point out that there are two activities along the value chain, the upstream activities (i.e. the production of intermediate inputs) and more downstream activities (e.g. the final assembly of products). Mexico's integration with the US in regional value chains is a story of contrasts because (OECD, undated:2):

“On average, the foreign value-added content in Mexico's gross exports is larger than in most OECD countries: 32%, compared to the OECD unweighted average of 28%. This is because Mexico is highly involved in international production networks and processing trade. Global value chains are particularly prevalent in electronics, where the foreign content share of more than 60% reflects specialisation in downstream stages of the value chain… and in transport equipment, where over 60% of imported intermediate inputs are destined for export…Services represent a significant share of the value of exports in most manufacturing industries, highlighting the fact that services are more traded than usually thought when taking into account value-added flows… Services account for 6% of gross exports but 31% of exported value-added. However this share of services value-added in exports is the lowest of OECD economies (the OECD unweighted average is 51%) and a third of the services content of exports comes from foreign embodied services, indicating that Mexican firms specialise in manufacturing sectors and in stages of production less intensive in services.”

Second step. Despite the deficits, the current account of the balance of payments has been sustainable over time. About financing of the negative balances we want to highlight the role of the worker's remittances and the foreign direct investment, as is shown in the next figure (Fig. 15).

Fig. 15.

Current account and worker's remittances, and foreign direct investment, 1960-2012, annual data.

(0,1MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the Balanced of Payments, Mexican Central Bank.

The deficits in manufacturing balance and in the current account have been financed without difficulty by, among others accounts, worker's remittances and foreign direct investment. However, this financing capacity constitutes a second best economic condition. In first place, because much of the macroeconomic stimulus that is originated in exports is lost in imports, with structural effects on the economy as we shall see in the next section. In second place, because it provokes some degree of vulnerability in the sense that the Mexican economy does not fully control, among others, to the foreign direct investment. In the third place, because it may represent a dangerous imbalanced in the case of accelerated economic growth. And in fourth place, because the success of our economy as exporting power or as complex economy is, to some extent, spurious. As a statistical result, the Granger causality tests, that are included in the Appendix, show that the causality runs exclusively from the economic growth rate to the current account ratio –that is consistent with the fact that the performance of the current account depends on the dynamic of the GDP and with the financing capacity of the deficit. All the above constitutes another complex stylized fact of the Mexican economy.

Total backward linkages

For Albert O. Hirschman, the quality of an investment sequence is detectable using as a tool the so-called linkages. A general definition of linkages is the following (Hirschman, 1987:206):

“A linkage (or linkage effect) was originally defined as a characteristic, more or less compelling sequence of investment decisions occurring in the course of industrialization and, more generally, of economic development… The resulting ‘strategy of unbalanced growth’ values investment decisions not only because of their immediate contribution to output, but because of the larger or smaller impulse such decisions are likely to impart to further investment, that is, because of their linkages.”

Specifically, Hirschman (1987:206) explains backward and forward linkages as follows:

“First, an existing industrial operation, relying initially on imports not only for its equipment and machinery, but also for many of its material inputs, would make for pressures towards the domestic manufacture of these inputs and eventually towards a domestic capital goods industry. This dynamic was called backward linkage, since the direction of the stimulus towards further investment flows from the finished article back towards the semi-processed or raw materials from which it is made or towards the machines which help make it… Another stimulus towards additional investment points in the other direction and is therefore called forward linkages: the existence of a given product line A, which is a final demand good or is used as an input in line B, acts as stimulant to the establishment of another line C which can also use A as an input.”

One of the characteristics of the research done by Hirschman (1987:206) was to introduce the economic policy dimension:

“The stimuli towards further investment are rather different for backward and forward linkages. The pressures towards backward linkage investment arise in part from normal entrepreneurial behavior, given the newly available market for intermediate goods. But there may also be resistance against such investments on the part of established industrialists who prefer to continue relying on imported inputs for price and quality reasons. At the same time, state policies favour backward linkage investments (which hold out the promise of foreign exchange savings and of a more ‘integrated’ industrial structure) through the promise of tariff protection and through various preferential foreign exchange and credit allocations, particularly in periods of foreign exchange stringency. The pressures towards forward linkage investment come primarily from the efforts of existing producers to increase and diversify the market for their products. In contrast to backward linkage, there will be only whole-hearted support for backward linkage on the part of existing domestic producers. On the other hand, official development policy is not likely to be particularly concerned with promoting forward linkage investments.”

There are available input-output matrices for the total and internal economy for the years 1993, 2003 and 2008. The difference between total economy and internal economy is that the first distributes the imports among the sectors in the intermediate demand matrix, or in other words, that the second one does not includes imports.

Using all the available information, we measure backward linkages, in first place the direct ones, that is, the so-called matrix A of coefficients, and in second place the direct and indirect ones, or total, the so-called Leontief inverse-matrix. Before showing the total backward linkages results, it is worth noting a caveat. The design of aggregation levels in the matrices is different. Therefore, the temporal comparison related with manufacturing should be taken with caution, to the extent it is well known that the aggregation plays a role in these kind of exercised (Fig. 16; Tables 4 and 5).

Fig. 16.

Direct and indirect linkages in the Mexican economy, internal matrices, 1993, 2003 and 2008.

(0,08MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.
Table 4.

Direct and indirect linkages in the Mexican economy and Manufacturing sector, internal matrices, Mexican pesos, 1993, 2003 and 2008.

  199320032008
  Economy  Manufacturing  Economy  Manufacturing  Economy  Manufacturing 
Mean  1.52  1.57  1.74  2.12  1.49  1.60 
Median  1.49  1.59  1.73  2.15  1.46  1.66 
Jarque-Bera  11.12  1.26  4.24  1.52  3.28  3.71 
Probability  0.00  0.53  0.12  0.47  0.19  0.16 
Observations  72  49  79  21  79  21 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.
Table 5.

Direct and indirect linkages in the Mexican economy and Manufacturing sector, internal matrices, ratios, 1993, 2003 and 2008.

Manufacturing/Economy
  1993  2003  2008 
Mean  1.03  1.22  1.07 
Median  1.07  1.24  1.14 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

The economic activities between the lines in the figure (Fig. 17) are the manufacturing ones. Therefore, in terms of its (mean and median) linkages, it is clear the relevant role of the manufacturing as a whole. Both in absolute and relative terms the year 2003 represents a step, that is to say, internal linkages observed their peak in the year 2003. In other words, absolute and relative values for the years 1993 and 2008 are similar. In conclusion, internal linkages won until 2003 were lost at the end of the reporting period (Tables 6 and 7).

Fig. 17.

Direct and indirect linkages in the Mexican Economy, total economy matrices, 1993, 2003 and 2008.

(0,08MB).
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.
Table 6.

Direct and indirect linkages, Mexican economy and manufacturing sector, total economy matrices, Mexican pesos, 1993 and 2003.

  199320032008
  Economy  Manufacturing  Economy  Manufacturing  Economy  Manufacturing 
Mean  1.74  1.86  1.83  2.38  1.89  2.44 
Median  1.77  1.59  1.82  2.39  1.81  2.36 
Jarque-Bera  0.76  0.1  5.7  19.46  20.96  44.17 
Probability  0.68  0.95  0.06  0.00  0.00  0.00 
Observations  72  49  79  21  79  21 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.
Table 7.

Direct and indirect linkages, Mexican economy and manufacturing sector, total economy matrices, ratios, 1993 and 2003.

  1993-20031993-2008Manufacturing/Economy
  Economy  Manufacturing  Economy  Manufacturing  1993  2003  2008 
Mean  1.05  1.28  1.08  1.31  1.07  1.30  1.30 
Median  1.03  1.50  1.03  1.48  0.90  1.31  1.30 

Between 1993 and 2003 and 2008, total linkages of the Mexican economy were stable, to be precise, based on medians its ratio was, repeatedly, 1.03. In contrast, in the case of the manufacturing the ratio jumped to a figure of 1.50 in 2003 and 1.48 in 2008. As a result, the relative ratios increased between the analyzed period. If we observe the total linkages from medians, the jump is evident, from 0.90 to 1.30. In this sense, the towing capacity of manufacturing sector over the Mexican economy would be a larger one if the manufacturing imports penetration had not been so intense since the trade liberalization. This complex stylized fact is partially explained by the existence of inefficient investment sequences during the analyzed period. Once again, this situation constitutes an opportunity area for the public agents and the private sector.

Conclusions

Our complex stylized facts are sets of information given in isolation, that is to say, are not parts of a complete economic model. However, as a cherry on the cake, we estimated a VAR model using the following variables: current account as a percentage of GDP (CAGDP), rate of inflation (DCPI), gross fixed capital formation as a percentage of GDP (GFCFratio), and the economic growth rate (DGDP). By the way, the order of the variables in the VAR was determined by our previous statistical analysis. In the Appendix we show the several tests used in order to verify its statistical adequacy. As in the case of the Granger causality tests that we have already talked about, our VAR conveniently involved stationary variables –which allowed us to avoid the problem of spurious results as a consequence of the presence of trend components. Bearing in mind that “if there is a reaction of one variable to an impulse in another variable we may call the latter casual the former” (Lütkepohl, 1991:43), the next figure (Fig. 18) shows the impulse response analysis relevant to our discussion.

Fig. 18.

Response to Cholesky one S.D. innovations (±2 S.E.), VAR model with four lags, 1960-2012.

(0,11MB).
Source: own caculations using data from the Balanced of Payments, Mexican Central Bank and the National Accounts System, INEGI.

As expected based on our proposed Hirschmanian facts, the reaction of inflation to the economic growth rate is null, that is to say, there is not a causal link between both variables; the reaction of the current account is negative, so we would better improve our export capabilities and reduce our import necessities; and the reaction of investment is positive –the so-called acceleration effect. The effect of the GDP on itself recalls us that the path of an economy may be in a positive one or a vicious one. I believe that the Mexican economy is trapped in the second case since long ago.

It seems that in Mexico, among other countries, decision makers suffer a sort of “fear of growing”. The complex stylized facts listed constitute a home remedy to attack such an unfounded fear.

From our Hirschmanian perspective, with heterodox touches, the set of economic policies should prioritize jointly, and without exception, the following goals:

  • Foster economic growth to bring it closer to its potential (grow, grow and grow is the mantra).

  • Increase the efficiency of both, public and private investment, in order to raise internal linkages, improve the current account sustainability, and reduce the external financing as a proportion of the current account.

  • Make protagonist to the manufacturing sector.

Without a doubt, the credibility of the Mexican Central Bank finally reached. It constitutes an historical achievement. Definitely, this institution has to maintain the inflation-free environment but also have to rescale some of their actions. According to our complex stylized facts, for example, there is not a contradiction between reduce the reference interest rate and the pursuit of its goal (reduce it, reduce it and reduce it is the mantra). Another issue is the related with the regulation of private banks. For the writer it is unclear its role and responsibilities, facing the Commission Banking and Securities, among other institutional participants. Despite the Mexican macroeconomic stability, with an inflation-free environment, the existence of an adequate number of banking competitors, and a benchmark interest rate of just a few percentage points, the credit to private agents in Mexico is scarce and extremely expensive. Since long ago, the only thing that is clear in consensus is the harmful role of the financial system in the Mexican economy (among others, Hanson, 2010; Kehoe & Ruhl, 2010).o

To some extent, the role of the exchange rate policy has been misunderstanding. As any key price constitutes a nominal anchor, and the super-peso may give us all a spurious purchasing power, but also influences the Mexican competitiveness. On one hand, one micro-economist would say that competitiveness is a matter of the firm. On the other hand, one way to support the proposed goals is to avoid overvaluation of the peso against the dollar. Indeed, the real effects of the overvalued peso are difficult to notice in the short run but are disastrous in the long run. Needless to say about the required consistency between the set of implemented policies in order to achieve our goals.

Finally, in our country has been implemented, implicitly and explicitly, industrial policy, at any level (National, State and Municipal, see Guerrero, 2012). Our crown jewel, the automobile industry, has developed in part through support programs implemented along the decades. Other success stories are computer and pharmaceutical industries. However, in order to reach the proposed goals, industrial policy must be upgraded. Certainly we need more champions and both, public and private agent, need to choose them without hesitation.

Appendix

Table 1A Sectors of the Mexican Economy.

S1  Primary 
S2  Mining 
S3  Electricity, water and gas 
S4  Construction 
S5  Manufacturing 
S6  Wholesale and Retail Trade 
S7  Transportation, postal service, and warehousing and storage 
S8  Finance and insurance, real state, rental and leasing 
S9  Professional, scientific, and technical services, management of companies and enterprises 
S10  Educational services, health care and social assistance 
S11  Arts, entertainment, and recreation, and public administration 
S12  Accommodation and food services 
S13  Legislative, justice, etc. 
Source: National Accounts System, INEGI.

Table 2A Correlation coefficients between sectors, in levels.

  S1  S2  S3  S4  S5  S6  S7  S8  S9  S10  S11  S12  S13 
S1  1.00                         
S2  0.70  1.00                       
S3  0.93  0.50  1.00                     
S4  0.95  0.61  0.95  1.00                   
S5  0.92  0.77  0.87  0.91  1.00                 
S6  0.96  0.70  0.95  0.96  0.97  1.00               
S7  0.95  0.55  0.99  0.97  0.91  0.98  1.00             
S8  0.90  0.40  0.98  0.92  0.81  0.91  0.97  1.00           
S9  0.96  0.63  0.96  0.98  0.94  0.99  0.98  0.93  1.00         
S10  0.98  0.63  0.98  0.96  0.92  0.98  0.99  0.95  0.98  1.00       
S11  0.92  0.53  0.93  0.98  0.88  0.94  0.96  0.92  0.96  0.95  1.00     
S12  0.45  0.44  0.41  0.59  0.61  0.54  0.46  0.32  0.57  0.41  0.56  1.00   
S13  -0.19  -0.61  0.06  -0.08  -0.11  -0.11  0.02  0.10  -0.08  -0.09  -0.05  0.05  1.00 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

Table 3A Correlation coefficients between sectors, in growth rates.

  DS1  DS2  DS3  DS4  DS5  DS6  DS7  DS8  DS9  DS10  DS11  DS12  DS13 
DS1  1.00                         
DS2  0.27  1.00                       
DS3  0.23  –0.05  1.00                     
DS4  0.26  0.37  0.42  1.00                   
DS5  0.22  0.56  0.42  0.70  1.00                 
DS6  0.21  0.55  0.40  0.79  0.95  1.00               
DS7  0.28  0.30  0.55  0.80  0.83  0.83  1.00             
DS8  0.19  –0.33  0.35  0.25  0.13  0.23  0.29  1.00           
DS9  0.27  0.29  0.45  0.75  0.74  0.81  0.82  0.32  1.00         
DS10  0.27  –0.12  0.39  0.31  0.20  0.23  0.38  –0.06  0.47  1.00       
DS11  0.12  0.13  0.28  0.83  0.58  0.64  0.84  0.23  0.64  0.33  1.00     
DS12  0.29  0.35  0.46  0.86  0.80  0.87  0.92  0.41  0.83  0.33  0.79  1.00   
DS13  –0.06  –0.27  0.38  0.24  0.27  0.26  0.40  0.34  0.15  0.06  0.29  0.38  1.00 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

Table 4A Granger causality test, inflation and economic growth.

Sample: 2007M01 2013M12
Null Hypothesis  F-Statistic  Prob. 
Lags: 1     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  7.01591  0.0100 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  0.01547  0.9014 
Lags: 2     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  3.31914  0.0424 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  0.81261  0.4482 
Lags: 3     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.93334  0.0403 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  0.63025  0.5982 
Lags: 4     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.46124  0.0550 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.04960  0.3895 
Lags: 5     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.20252  0.0668 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.04187  0.4023 
Lags: 6     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.22587  0.0547 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.11564  0.3659 
Lags: 7     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  3.28525  0.0060 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.15912  0.3429 
Lags: 8     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.61471  0.0187 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.03301  0.4253 
Lags: 9     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.88389  0.0091 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.24145  0.2955 
Lags: 10     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  3.13974  0.0046 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.30595  0.2596 
Lags: 11     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.99202  0.0059 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.10055  0.3871 
Lags: 12     
DCPI does not Granger Cause DGEAI  2.12544  0.0411 
DGEAI does not Granger Cause DCPI  1.18837  0.3288 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

Table 5A Granger causality test, current account as % of GDP and economic growth.

Sample: 1960 2012
Null Hypothesis  F-Statistic  Prob. 
Lags: 1     
CAGDP does not Granger Cause DGDP  2.18770  0.1457 
DGDP does not Granger Cause CAGDP  10.1214  0.0026 
Lags: 2     
CAGDP does not Granger Cause DGDP  3.02537  0.0585 
DGDP does not Granger Cause CAGDP  3.98872  0.0254 
Lags: 3     
CAGDP does not Granger Cause DGDP  2.19315  0.1030 
DGDP does not Granger Cause CAGDP  3.62781  0.0204 
Source: own calculations using data from the Balanced of Payments, Mexican Central Bank and the National Accounts System, INEGI.

Table 6A Granger causality test, investment ratio and economic growth.

Sample: 1960 2012
Null Hypothesis  F-Statistic  Prob. 
Lags: 2     
GFCFRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  3.49056  0.0390 
DGDP does not Granger Cause GFCFRATIO  0.87252  0.4248 
Lags: 4     
GFCFRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  1.10754  0.3668 
DGDP does not Granger Cause GFCFRATIO  0.83180  0.5132 
Lags: 6     
GFCFRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  0.74157  0.6201 
DGDP does not Granger Cause GFCFRATIO  1.04264  0.4160 
Lags:2     
DGDP does not Granger Cause BUILDINGSRATIO  0.36391  0.6970 
BUILDINGSRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  0.08747  0.9164 
Lags:4     
DGDP does not Granger Cause BUILDINGSRATIO  0.30185  0.8749 
BUILDINGSRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  0.15984  0.9573 
Lags:6  0.91119  0.4991 
DGDP does not Granger Cause BUILDINGSRATIO  0.14865  0.9880 
BUILDINGSRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP     
Lags:2     
MACHINERYRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  4.99559  0.0110 
DGDP does not Granger Cause MACHINERYRATIO  0.17030  0.8440 
Lags:4     
MACHINERYRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  1.61921  0.1888 
DGDP does not Granger Cause MACHINERYRATIO  0.70452  0.5937 
Lags:6     
MACHINERYRATIO does not Granger Cause DGDP  1.05391  0.4094 
DGDP does not Granger Cause MACHINERYRATIO  1.33794  0.2685 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI. In order to determine the VARs lags the following test were applied: LR: sequential modified LR test statistic, FPE: Final prediction error, AIC: Akaike information criterion, SC: Schwarz information criterion, and HQ: Hannan-Quinn information criterion. We also applied a set of tests to verify the no-autocorrelation, the normality, the no-heteroskedasticity, weak exogeneity, and the stability condition of the VARs.

Table 7A Database.

  CAGDP  DCPI  GFCFRATIO  BUILDINGSRATIO  MACHINERYRATIO  DGDP 
1963  –1.7199  0.3534  17.22  11.30  5.92  7.5494 
1964  –2.2907  4.2254  18.78  11.86  6.92  11.0038 
1965  –2.1424  2.0270  18.37  11.03  7.34  6.1487 
1966  –1.9004  1.2141  18.84  11.84  6.99  6.0962 
1967  –2.3775  2.9444  19.84  12.60  7.24  5.8549 
1968  –2.6693  1.8008  19.87  12.36  7.50  9.4233 
1969  –2.2198  2.6015  20.57  13.05  7.52  3.4187 
1970  –2.6304  5.0034  20.83  12.84  7.99  6.5025 
1971  –2.1933  5.4690  19.52  12.15  7.38  3.7625 
1972  –2.1005  4.9437  20.41  12.57  7.84  8.2288 
1973  –2.2710  12.0819  21.76  13.20  8.56  7.8611 
1974  –3.4063  23.7840  22.27  13.20  9.07  5.7768 
1975  –3.6298  14.9445  23.05  13.42  9.63  5.7445 
1976  –3.7981  15.8247  21.98  13.38  8.60  4.4174 
1977  –1.7664  29.0641  19.74  12.59  7.15  3.3906 
1978  –2.1997  17.4573  21.07  13.09  7.98  8.9569 
1979  –2.5003  18.1913  23.03  13.49  9.54  9.6982 
1980  –3.8167  26.3516  24.76  13.89  10.87  9.2333 
1981  –4.6815  27.9338  26.43  14.52  11.91  8.7726 
1982  –2.7655  58.9134  22.13  13.67  8.46  –0.6279 
1983  2.9265  101.8749  16.57  11.06  5.51  –4.1963 
1984  1.7475  65.4488  17.03  11.10  5.93  3.6102 
1985  0.3932  57.7484  17.92  11.22  6.70  2.5934 
1986  –0.8462  86.2333  16.40  10.49  5.92  –3.7539 
1987  2.4137  131.8274  16.09  10.49  5.59  1.8557 
1988  –0.9998  114.1622  16.80  10.18  6.62  1.2454 
1989  –2.0520  20.0079  17.30  10.14  7.17  3.3485 
1990  –2.2117  26.6517  18.73  10.51  8.22  4.4446 
1991  –3.6551  22.6624  19.57  10.36  9.22  3.6268 
1992  –5.3456  15.5079  21.11  10.70  10.41  2.8049 
1993  –4.7940  9.7515  18.56  9.97  8.59  0.6004 
1994  –5.6109  6.9658  19.26  10.24  9.02  4.4583 
1995  –0.4670  34.9993  14.58  8.46  6.12  –6.2180 
1996  –0.6280  34.3784  16.14  8.98  7.17  5.1398 
1997  –1.5978  20.6256  18.30  9.30  9.00  6.7755 
1998  –3.2206  15.9284  19.24  9.22  10.02  4.9065 
1999  –2.4207  16.5856  19.95  9.31  10.64  3.8732 
2000  –2.7506  9.4916  20.84  9.27  11.57  6.6020 
2001  –2.4375  6.3677  19.69  8.85  10.84  –0.1570 
2002  –2.0025  5.0307  19.41  9.09  10.32  0.8267 
2003  –1.1489  4.5469  18.94  12.51  6.43  1.3515 
2004  –0.8894  4.6884  19.66  12.63  7.03  4.0534 
2005  –0.9976  3.9881  20.47  12.74  7.73  3.2054 
2006  –0.7806  3.6295  21.39  13.08  8.31  5.1502 
2007  –1.3806  3.9668  22.15  13.28  8.87  3.2602 
2008  –1.8097  5.1250  23.09  13.68  9.41  1.1906 
2009  –0.8734  5.2974  21.66  13.63  8.03  –5.9539 
2010  –0.3109  4.1567  20.64  12.85  7.79  5.2811 
2011  –1.0328  3.4074  21.48  12.81  8.67  3.8877 
2012  –1.2128  4.1115  21.88  12.84  9.04  3.9245 
Source: own calculations using data from the National Accounts System, INEGI.

References
[Basu and Fernald, 2001]
Basu, S. & Fernald, J. (2001). Why is productivity procyclical? Why do we care? In C.R. Hulten, E.R. Dean, & M.J. Harper (Eds.), New developments in productivity analysis (pp. 225-302). NBER. University of Chicago Press, printed in USA.
[Carstens, 2013a]
Carstens, A. (2013a). The bagehot lecture emerging markets. In The Buttonwood Gathering 2013. The Economist. Searching for financial stability, New York City, October 30. Available from: http://www.banxico.org.mx/index.html, date accessed april 29, 2014.
[Carstens, 2013b]
Carstens, A. (2013b). La economía mexicana. Presentación ante el Senado de la República, Banco de México. Available from: http://www.banxico.org.mx/index.html, date accessed april 29, 2014.
[Corrado et al., 2005]
Corrado, C., Haltiwanger, J., & Sichel, D. (Eds.) (2005). Measuring capital in the new economy. NBER Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 65, University of Chicago Press, printed in USA.
[Durlauf et al., 2005]
S.N. Durlauf, P.A. Johnson, J.R.W. Temple.
Growth econometrics.
Handbook of economic growth Vol. 1A,
[Ellerman, 2004]
D. Ellerman.
Revisiting hirschman on development assistance and unbalanced growth.
Eastern Economic Journal, 30 (2004), pp. 311-331
[Enders, 2004]
W. Enders.
Applied econometric time series.
Wiley series in probability and statistics, second edition, printed in USA, (2004),
[Engels, 1885]
Engels, F. (1885). Preface to the first edition. Capital. Vol. II. Available from: http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1885-c2/ch00.htm, date accessed april 29, 2014.
[Granger, 1992]
Granger, C.W.J. (1992). What are we learning about the long run? Working Paper No. 92-38, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.
[Griliches, 1994]
Z. Griliches.
Productivity R&D, and the data constraint.
American Economic Review, 84 (1994), pp. 1-23
[Guerrero, 2008a]
C. Guerrero.
Sesgos de medición del índice nacional de precios al consumidor, 2002-2007.
Investigación Económica, 67 (2008), pp. 37-65
[Guerrero, 2008b]
C. Guerrero.
Sesgo de medición del PIB derivado de los cambios en la calidad del sector TI: México 2000-2004.
Estudios Económicos, 23 (2008), pp. 253-280
[Guerrero, 2009]
C. Guerrero.
Contribution of the information and communication technology sector to Mexican Economic growth from 1999 to 2003.
EconoQuantum, 6 (2009), pp. 11-30
[Guerrero, 2012]
Guerrero, C. (2012). La manufactura mexicana, diagnóstico de su estructura y programas locales de apoyo: prácticas, logros y pendientes hacia una política industrial nacional. LC/MEX/L.1084, ECLAC.
[Guerrero, 2013]
C. Guerrero.
A Look at capital measurements in the U. S. and Mexican Economic Censuses.
Reality, Data and Space: International Journal of Statistics and Geography INEGI, 4 (2013), pp. 40-51
[Hanson, 2010]
G.H. Hanson.
Why isn’t Mexico rich?.
Journal of Economic Literature, 84 (2010), pp. 987-1004
[Hausmann et al., 2011]
R. Hausmann, C.A. Hidalgo, S. Bustos, M. Coscia, S. Chung, J. Jiménez, A. Simoes, M.A. Yildrim.
The atlas of economic complexity.
Harvard Kenney School and MIT, electronic book, (2011),
[Hirschman, 1959]
A.O. Hirschman.
The strategy of economic development.
Second printing, first published 1958. Yale University Press, (1959),
[Hirschman, 1985]
A.O. Hirschman.
A dissenter's confession: ‘The Strategy of Economic Development’ revisited”.
Pioneers in development,
[Hirschman, 1987]
A.O. Hirschman.
Linkages.
The new palgrave. A dictionary of economics, pp. 206-208
[Hodrick and Prescott, 1997]
R.J. Hodrick, E.C. Prescott.
Postwar U.S. business cycles: an empirical investigation.
Journal of Money Credit, and Banking, 29 (1997), pp. 1-16
[Howlett and Morgan, 2011]
Howlett, P. & Morgan, M. (Eds.) (2011). How well do facts travel? Cambridge University Press, printed in USA.
[INEGI, 2013]
INEGI.
Productividad total de los factores: modelo KLEMS.
Boletín de Investigación, 02/13, (2013), pp. 1-10
[Kaldor, 1961]
N. Kaldor.
Capital accumulation and economic growth.
The theory of capital, pp. 177-222
[Kaldor, 1966]
Kaldor, N. (1966), Causes of the Slow Rate of Growth of the United Kingdom, Cambridge University Press.
[Kaldor, 1967]
N. Kaldor.
Strategic factors in economic development. Ithaca, New York State.
School of Industrial and Labour Relations, Cornell University, (1967),
[Kehoe and Ruhl, 2010]
T.J. Kehoe, K.J. Ruhl.
Why have Economic reforms in Mexico not generated Growth?.
Journal of Economic Literature, 48 (2010), pp. 1005-1027
[Keynes, 1936]
Keynes, J.M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest, and money. Open access, http://cas.umkc.edu/economics/people/facultypages/kregel/courses/econo745/winter2011/generaltheory.pdf, date accessed april 29, 2014.
[Keynes, 1939]
Keynes, J.M. (1939). Preface to the French edition. In The general theory of employment, interest, and money, (1936). Open access, http://cas.umkc.edu/economics/people/facultypages/kregel/courses/econo745/winter2011/generaltheory.pdf, date accessed april 29, 2014.
[Kurz, 2012]
H.D. Kurz.
Two critics of marginalist theory: Piero Straffa and John Maynard Keynes.
Investigación Económica, 71 (2012), pp. 23-54
[Leamer, 2007]
Leamer, E. (2007). Housing is the business cycle. Working Paper 13428, NBER.
[Lequiller and Blades, 2007]
F. Lequiller, D. Blades.
Understanding national accounts. Reprinted.
OECD Publishing, (2007),
[López and Assous, 2010]
J. López, M. Assous.
Michal Kalecki.
Palgrave Macmillan, (2010),
[Lütkepohl, 1991]
H. Lütkepohl.
Introduction to multiple time series analysis.
Springer-Verlag, printed in Germany, (1991),
[OECD, 2012]
OECD (2012). OECD compendium of productivity indicators 2012. OECD Publishing, Paris.
[OECD, in press]
OECD (undated). OECD/WTO trade in value-added (TIVA) database: Mexico. Available from: http://www.oecd.org/sti/ind/TiVA%20Mexico2.pdf, date accessed april 29, 2014.
[Phillips, 2003]
P.C.B. Phillips.
Law and limits of econometrics.
Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper, (2003), pp. 1397
[Presidencia de la República, 2013]
Presidencia de la República (2013). Criterios generales de política económica 2014. Disponible en: http://www.shcp.gob.mx, date accessed april 29, 2014.
[Schreyer, 1996]
P. Schreyer.
Quality adjustment of price indices in information and communication technology industries: simulation of effects on measured real output in five OECD countries.
Industry Productivity: International Comparison and Measurement Issues, OECD Proceedings, (1996),
[Schreyer, 1998]
Schreyer P. Information and communication technology and the measurement of real output, final demand and productivity. OECD STI Working Paper, 1998/1998 2
[Shiau et al., 2002]
A. Shiau, J. Kilpatrick, M. Matthews.
Seven percent growth for Mexico?. A quantitative assessment of Mexico's investment requirements.
Journal of Policy Modeling, 24 (2002), pp. 781-798
[Steindl, 1976]
Steindl, J. (1976). Maturity and stagnation in American capitalism. Reprinted of the 1952 ed. published by Blackwell, which was issued as Monograph 4 of the Oxford University Institute of Statistics.
[White and Granger, 2011]
H. White, C.W.L. Granger.
Consideration of trends in time series.
Journal of Time Series Econometrics, 3 (2011), pp. 2

Suffice to remember the following (Durlauf, Johnson, & Temple, 2005:558): “As illustrated in Appendix 2 of this chapter, approximately as many growth determinants have been proposed as there are countries for which data are available. It is hard to believe that all these determinants are central, yet the embarrassment of riches also makes it hard to identify the subset that truly matters.”

Currently, the study of “facts” is a valid approach in the sciences. A refined example is the following (Howlett & Morgan, 2011:xv-xvi): “And because they are such independent pieces of knowledge, facts have the possibility to travel, and indeed some circulate freely, far and wide… They are not just an essential category of the way we talk in modern times, but provide one of the forms of knowledge upon which we act.” For Leamer, there are (2007:51) “pertinent facts”. In his role as editor of Volume II of Capital, Engels (1885) complained as follows: “Factual material for illustration would be collected, but barely arranged, much less worked out.” And Kurz (2012:35) criticized the new “facts” produced by the marginalists.

Professor Granger (1992:2) recalls us the Keynesian injunction: “The most famous truism in economics is the statement by Lord Keynes, that ‘in the long run we are all dead.’ It does not imply that the long run is unimportant, after all institutions can exist for a long time, the Royal Economic Society being an example, and most of us are altruistic enough to be concerned about the economic well-being of our children and grandchildren. What Keynes was actually emphasizing was that the study of the short run is also important, as his statement continues. ‘Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if in tempestuous seasons they can only tell us that when the storm is long past, the ocean is fiat again.’ I doubt if that is the kind of forecast made by current economists.” Nevertheless, the Governor of the Bank of Mexico has its own ideas (Carstens, 2013a:4): “Countercyclical monetary policies should be applied as one should drink tequila: in moderation”.

It is worthwhile to underline, in first place, that in order to determine the smoothing parameter, Hodrick and Prescott (1997) analyzed the US economy between 1947-53, 1953-68, and 1968-73; in second place, that the authors applied their filter to a set of variables between 1947 and 1993; and in third place, the signal extracted was labeled as a (non-stochastic) trend, whatever that means (Phillips, 2003; White & Granger 2011). According to Enders (2004:225): “a word of caution is in order. Since the HP filter is a function that smoothes the trend, it has been shown to introduce spurious fluctuations into the irregular component of a series.” All the above raise the question about the usefulness of the computerized tool not only to analyze the Mexican economy but also the US economy itself in the present.

The following quotation addresses the quality of official statistics (Lequiller & Blades, 2007:36): “National accounts’ data are therefore approximations. It is not even possible to give a summary figure of the accuracy of the GDP. Indeed, national accounts, and in particular GDP, are not the result of a single big survey for which one might compile a confidence interval. They are the result of combining a complex mix of data from many sources, many of which require adjustment to put them into a national accounts database and which are further adjusted to improve coherence, often using non-scientific methods.”

In 1994, Zvi Griliches argued that the fraction of output that is hard to measure has been growing over time. Its extension proposed by Corrado, Haltiwanger, and Sichel (2005:2) is equally true, that is, “that the fraction of capital that is challenging to measure has been growing over time as well.”

It should be clear that any growth accounting exercise should be taken with extremely caution (see for example INEGI, 2013). Why are the data no better? Griliches (1994:14) answered: “At least three observations come to mind: (i) the measurement problems are really hard, (ii) economists have little clout in Washington, especially as far as data-collection activities are concerned… (iii) we ourselves do not put enough emphasis on the value of data and data collection in our training of graduates students and in the reward structure of our profession.”

This represents one of the three distinctions of The General Theory with respect to the Orthodoxy (Keynes, 1939:10): “I believe that economics everywhere up to recent times has been dominated, much more than has been understood, by the doctrines associated with the name of J.-B. Say. It is true that his ‘law of markets’ has been long abandoned by most economists; but they have not extricated themselves from his basic assumptions and particularly from his fallacy that demand is created by supply. Say was implicitly assuming that the economic system was always operating up to its full capacity, so that a new activity was always in substitution for, and never in addition to, some other activity. Nearly all subsequent economic theory has depended on, in the sense that it has required, this same assumption. Yet a theory so based is clearly incompetent to tackle the problems of unemployment and of the trade cycle.”

Likewise, the viewpoints of economists with K about the degree of use of capital stock are useful in order to explain not only the economic performance, but also recent stylized facts, among others the cyclical patterns of labor and multifactor productivity growth (see OECD, 2012). For the growth theory, the empirical evidence collected by Anita Wölfl within the Organization is valuable in the sense that productivities are shown as outcomes, not as sources, of the economic growth. See also Basu and Fernald (2001).

About the originality of its hypothesis, Albert Hirschman (1985:87) wrote: “A striking case of convergence with my thinking is Paul Streeten's article ‘Unbalanced growth’, Oxford Economic Papers, N.S., vol. 2 (June 1959), pp. 167-90. His article and my book, The Strategy of Economic Development (whose working title was for a long time ‘The Economics of Unbalanced Growth’), were written quite independently. Paul Streeten tells me that the printing of his article was delayed for several months by a printers’ strike, otherwise his defense of unbalanced growth might have come out before mine.”

The Appendix includes specific information about sectors, that is, its correlation coefficients in levels and in growth rates.

In Section 1 entitled “What do we mean by economic complexity”, the authors answer (p. 18): “Ultimately, the complexity of an economy is related to the multiplicity of useful knowledge embedded in it. For a complex society to exist, and to sustain itself, people who know about design, marketing, finance, technology, human resource management, operations and trade law must be able to interact and combine their knowledge to make products. These same products cannot be made in societies that are missing parts of this capability set. Economic complexity, therefore, is expressed in the composition of a country's productive output and reflects the structures that emerge to hold and combine knowledge.”

A non-testable hypothesis is the following (Kehoe & Ruhl, 2010:1021): “Given our question of why Mexico stagnates while China grows, we need to ask of all of these papers why the mechanisms that they study worked in China but not in Mexico. A potential answer is that most of Mexico's trade and FDI inflows are with the United States. It may be that the predominance of intrafirm trade between Mexico and the United States reduces the incentives toward competition and innovation that would arise from trade and foreign investment reforms.”

Remarkably, a new challenge for the economic measurement appears with this literature (OECD & WTO, undated:1): “With the globalization of production, there is a growing awareness that conventional trade statistics may give a misleading perspective of the importance of trade to economic growth and income and that ‘what you see is not what you get’… This reflects the fact that trade flows are measured gross and that the value of products that cross borders several times for further processing are counted multiple times. Policymakers are increasingly aware of the necessity of complementing existing statistics with new indicators better tuned to the reality of global manufacturing, where products are ‘Made in the World’.”

It should be noted that in no way it is possible to consider sufficient the so-called “lack of contract enforcement” as the explanation of the obscene gap between active and passive interest rates. And talking about the “rule of law”, in Mexico the minimum wage, which is set by the authority itself, violates the Labor Law in the sense that its amount is not enough to buy the food basket –ones again established by the authority itself.

Copyright © 2015. Universidad Nacinal Autónoma de México
Opciones de artículo