covid
Buscar en
Cuadernos de Economía
Toda la web
Inicio Cuadernos de Economía Real output costs of financial crises: A loss distribution approach
Información de la revista
Vol. 37. Núm. 103.
Páginas 13-28 (enero - abril 2014)
Compartir
Compartir
Descargar PDF
Más opciones de artículo
Visitas
6046
Vol. 37. Núm. 103.
Páginas 13-28 (enero - abril 2014)
Article
Acceso a texto completo
Real output costs of financial crises: A loss distribution approach
Costes de la producción real de las crisis financieras: un enfoque de distribución de pérdidas
Visitas
6046
Daniel Kappa,
Autor para correspondencia
, Marco Vegab
a University of Paris 1 – Panthéon‐Sorbonne and Paris School of Economics, Paris, France
b Central Bank of Peru and Universidad Católica del Perú, Lima, Peru
Este artículo ha recibido
Información del artículo
Resumen
Texto completo
Bibliografía
Descargar PDF
Estadísticas
Figuras (5)
Mostrar másMostrar menos
Tablas (19)
Table 1. Severity of financial crises (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 2. Severity of crises by regions—all crises (Losses as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 3. Severity by income groups (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 4. Severity over time—all crises (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 5. Features of the PDF of total losses.
Table 6. LDA, Losses in constant 2005 USD, over periods of five years, as percentage of 2005 World GDP.
Table 7. Losses after financial crises (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 8. Losses after currency crises (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 9. Losses after banking crises (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 10. Losses after debt crises (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 11. Losses after twin crises—currency and debt (as percentage of initial GDP.
Table 12. Losses after twin crises—currency and banking (as percentage of initial GDP.
Table 13. Losses after twin crises—debt and banking (as percentage of initial GDP.
Table 14. Losses after all twin crises (as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 15. Severity of crises by regions—all crises (losses as percentage of initial GDP).
Table 16. Average severity of crises by income groups (percentage of initial GDP).
Table 17. Average features of the PDF of total losses (more cases).
Table 18. Average features of the PDF of total losses (more cases).
Table 19. USA 2007 banking crisis losses (percentage of 2007 real GDP).
Mostrar másMostrar menos
Abstract

We study cross‐country GDP losses due to financial crises in terms of frequency (number of loss events per period) and severity (loss per occurrence). We perform the Loss Distribution Approach (LDA) to estimate a multi‐country aggregate GDP loss probability density function and the percentiles associated to extreme events due to financial crises. We find that output losses arising from financial crises are strongly heterogeneous and that currency crises lead to smaller output losses than debt and banking crises. Extreme global financial crises episodes, occurring with a one percent probability every five years, lead to losses between 2.95 and 4.54% of world GDP.

Keywords:
Financial crisis
Severity
Frequency
Loss Distribution Approach
JEL classification:
C19
G01
G17
G22
G32
Resumen

Se estudian pérdidas de PIB por países originadas por crisis financieras en términos de frecuencia (número de eventos de pérdida por periodo) y severidad (pérdidas por ocurrencia). Se utiliza el enfoque Loss Distribution Approach (LDA) para calcular la función de densidad de probabilidad de pérdidaagregada de PIB a través de los países de la muestra y para extraer los percentiles asociados a eventos extremos ligados a crisis financieras.Se encuentra que las pérdidas de producción derivadas de las crisis financieras son muy heterogéneas. También encontramos que las crisis de tipo de cambio generan menos pérdidas de producción que las crisis de deuda soberana o las crisis bancarias. Los periodos extremos de crisis financiera global tienen lugar con una probabilidad del 1% cada 5años y conllevan pérdidas de entre el 2,95% y el 4,45% del PIB mundial.

Palabras clave:
Crisis financieras
Severidad
Frecuencia
Loss Distribution Approach
Texto completo
1Introduction

Financial crises have played a quintessential role after the collapse of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. Episodes like the Latin American debt crises in the 1980s, the 1987 Black Monday, the 1992–1993 ERM crisis, the 1994–1995 Tequila crisis, the 1997–1998 South East Asian meltdown, the 1998–1999 Brazilian and Russian crisis, the 2000–2001 Turkish crisis, the 2001 Argentine crisis and the 2007–2009 global financial crisis all resemble disaster events, just like hurricanes or earthquakes.

Like catastrophic events, financial crises can be characterized by frequency and severity. In fact, analysis made in the financial crises literature often refers to terms such as frequency and severity (see Bordo et al., 2001). The insurance and operational risk theory and practice offer toolkits to analyze frequency and severity of losses as well as aggregate losses due to catastrophic or operational risk events. Given that the losses to country economies from financial crises (in terms of GDP drop or forgone GDP) are similar to catastrophic losses, we can apply the Loss Distribution Approach (LDA) familiar in the actuarial literature to analyze frequency and severity of losses and thus study rare events and their probabilities (see Panjer, 2006; Shevchenko, 2011). To the best of our knowledge, there is no attempt to quantify the frequency and severity of financial crises using the LDA.

The advantage of the LDA is that we can analyze frequency of events and severity in a separate fashion and then combine them to obtain a global loss probability density function. In the study of GDP losses arising from financial crisis, it is of interest to study frequency and severity on their own as shown in Bordo et al. (2001).

The LDA allows us to estimate a multi‐country aggregate GDP loss distribution and thus estimate conditional losses in the event of a financial crisis occurring in the near future. We can also determine the probability of rare economic disasters as defined for example in Barro (2006). In contrast to Barro (2006), however, we do not make any assumptions on the channel through which crises occur (e.g. catastrophic events like earthquakes or regular/cyclical disaster events).

In terms of methodology, we use the financial crises database of Laeven and Valencia (2008) to date financial crises across 170 countries from 1970 onwards. The number of such events over a predetermined period is called the frequency of events. We then estimate output losses per financial crises event with a number of methods. Afterwards, we aggregate country output losses across events over the period. Since a particular crisis event can generate output losses over various years, we set the span of analysis to be five years. Finally, we compound frequency and severity to generate a loss probability density of aggregate losses that allows us to report standard risk measures.

We find that output losses after financial crises are strongly heterogeneous and a large number of countries never recovered their pre‐crises growth rates or trends. Also, we show that currency crises lead to smaller output losses than debt and banking crises, while the largest losses are found after debt crises. The presence of a debt crisis also exacerbates any of the other two forms of crises, while the presence of a currency crisis in the wake of a debt or banking crisis diminishes output losses through faster recovery. Banking and debt crises alone are found to be more severe than twin crises consisting of banking and currency crises or debt and currency crises.

The LDA approach leads us to conclude that mean worldwide costs of financial crises within periods of 5 years are in the range of 0.52–0.81% of 2005 world GDP. Extreme crises episodes, occurring with a one percent probability, can lead to losses between 2.95% and 4.54% of world GDP.

The analysis of losses produced in the paper can be a useful tool in discussions about the existence of insurance against the risk of financial crises at the aggregate level. For example, Caballero (2003) proposes such an arrangement for emerging market economies.

In what follows, we will provide a short literature review and discuss the possibilities at hand to calculate output costs of financial crises. In Section 3, we introduce the methodology of crisis identification and loss calculation, while the Loss Distribution Approach is explained in Section 4. Results are presented in Section 5. Section 6 discusses a potential form of international insurance and Section 7 concludes.

2The costs of financial crises

In order to quantify the costs of financial crises, we need to define a metric. Studies on this subject use a varied set of cost measures. Costs have been estimated as fiscal costs, costs to the stock market, and output costs. Among studies analyzing the same kinds of losses, methodologies also differ. In addition, one of the main obstacles to measuring losses caused by financial crises is how to identify losses only due to financial crisis and not arising from other contemporaneous factors.

2.1Fiscal costs, costs to the stock market and output losses

In an attempt to quantify the costs of banking crises to the economy, Hoggarth et al. (2002) consider direct resolution costs as well as broader welfare costs to the economy, approximated by output losses. They argue that resolution costs are a rather limited proxy for costs incurred through banking crises, as they may reflect a transfer of income from taxpayers to banks rather than costs imposed to the economy as a whole. The authors reason that there could be a positive correlation between fiscal costs and output losses if crises are systemic. On the other hand, if fiscal costs are a good proxy for effective crisis resolution, higher spending on crisis resolution should lead to lower output losses during a crisis period. No clear statistical relationship between fiscal costs and length of crises is found, while output losses and the length of crises do depict a clear positive correlation.

Frydl (1999) presents a comparative analysis of prior banking crises studies. As one of the reasons for the non‐significant statistical relation between resolution costs and crises length, he claims that resolution costs usually measure fiscal costs of banking crises, which are often subject to various errors and do not incorporate many indirect costs to the government or the economy. Having dismissed fiscal costs as a reliable indicator for crisis severity, Boyd et al. (2000) use the discounted value of corporate returns to measure the impact of crises. Under the condition that corporate profits represent a relatively constant fraction of total output, a decline in the real values of stock prices at the onset of a crisis in percentage terms is approximately equal to the decline in the present discounted value of total output.

With regards to the impact and depth of currency crises, possible measures to be considered (in addition to output losses) are the loss of international reserves and the depreciation of the real exchange rate (Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999). However, the most popular method is to proxy costs to the economy with GDP losses, given that economic growth is a natural final performance indicator. This is the approach we follow in this paper.

We identify two strains of literature approximating real GDP losses due to financial crises. The first uses a dummy variable approach to estimate growth losses over samples of countries, studies such as Demirguc‐Kunt et al. (2006), Gupta et al. (2007), Hanna and Huang (2002) and Barro (2001) follow this path. The second approach proxies welfare losses by comparing GDP during a crisis period with some estimate of potential output. Hoggarth et al. (2002) is one representative study of this latter approach. It estimates potential output assuming that output would have grown at the same constant rate based on its past performance. Various studies, such as Bordo et al. (2001), Aziz et al. (2000), Frydl (1999), Boyd et al. (2000, 2005) and Cecchetti et al. (2009) calculate output losses from banking crises in a similar fashion, even though their trend estimates are based on differing pre‐crises windows, methods, definitions about onsets, ends and durations of crisis episodes.

A main criticism of the dummy variable approach is that it can only identify average magnitudes of growth contractions associated with crises for all countries. It therefore does not seem to be well suited for highly heterogeneous losses. Output costs calculated through cross‐section or panel data regressions are usually found to be lower than losses calculated based on output gap estimations.

In a comparative analysis, Angkinand (2008) suggests that the output gap approach is more appropriate than the dummy variable approach in capturing the output costs of crises. This is so because the individual output costs across crises vary substantially. Our loss estimation methodology therefore follows the output gap approach.

2.2Output gap calculations2.2.1Determining the length of a crisis

The literature does not offer a unanimously agreed method to date the beginning of financial crises. Banking crisis start dates are usually defined through a mixture of quantitative and qualitative criteria. Caprio and Klingebiel (1996) rely on the assessment of finance professionals. Including and expanding on this approach, Demirguc‐Kunt and Detragiache (1998) compile five studies of banking crises’ starting dates. Other studies identifying banking crises’ dates are Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999), and Lindgren et al. (1996).

The onset of a currency crisis is generally defined as a situation whereby a sufficiently large depreciation of the domestic currency occurs,1 often accompanied by a loss in international reserves, while a debt crisis takes place in the event of a country defaulting or renegotiating all or parts of its private debt. The most recent financial crises compilation, widely used in previous empirical studies, stems from Laeven and Valencia (2008) and comprises banking, currency, and debt crises over the period 1970–2008.

To date the end of a crisis episode, one possibility is to define the end date based on “expert” opinions or on the “consensus” view from various studies. An alternative is to define the end of a crisis endogenously once a country returns to a certain pre‐crisis growth rate or recovers its potential output growth path.

Studies determining the end of a crisis based on the recovery of the average growth rate of a pre‐crisis window are, among others, Bordo et al. (2001) and Aziz et al. (2000). Authors such as Boyd et al. (2005) argue that summing up deviations from an estimated trend up to the point at which the observed growth rate returns to its pre‐crisis average is problematic since output typically remains well below its pre‐crisis absolute output trend once the growth rate has recovered.

Cecchetti et al. (2009) avoid calculating a counterfactual and define the end of a crisis as the point in time when real GDP has reached its absolute pre‐crisis level. This method is problematic in at least two ways. First, the method does not take opportunity costs of foregone output growth into account. Second, the method implies that a crisis is only counted as such if output growth actually turns negative during the crisis year. It can be argued, however, that a financial crisis has negative effects without having caused an actual recession, e.g. through a transitory or permanent slowdown in growth. Moreover, since potential growth rates vary across countries, dating the end of a recession by reaching its pre‐crisis level of real GDP can lead to an underestimation of total losses incurred.

2.2.2Estimation of a counterfactual

To be able to measure output losses during crisis periods according to the methods described above, it is necessary to compare actual output with its trend level. There are a handful of approaches to estimate trend GDP levels. They differ mainly by the pre‐crisis time window chosen, which in turn depends on the assumption about financial crises either following economic booms or a slowdown in economic activity.

Hoggarth et al. (2002) assume that output would have grown at a constant rate based on past growth performance and extrapolate linear three and ten‐year trends, while Bordo et al. (2001) use five‐year pre‐crisis trends. In a more recent study, Boyd et al. (2005) extrapolate a trend using both, a country's own growth rate and the world growth rate and apply break regressions to determine the end of crises episodes. Instead, Frydl (1999) applies ten‐year pre‐crisis periods and Boyd et al. (2000) extrapolate linear pre‐crisis growth trends.

A large part of the heterogeneity in the magnitude of output losses in the study of crises stems from the calculation of trend output. Studies, such as Kindleberger (1978), Borio et al. (1994) and Logan (2001) find that banking crises follow economic booms. In this case, a trend estimated over a short period prior to a crisis would overestimate potential output and lead to an overestimation of crisis length and depth. On the other hand, studies such as Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) or Gorton (1988) find that banking crises are often preceded by a slowdown of economic activity, in which case losses would be understated.

If one assumes that pre‐crisis growth deviates (in either direction) from the long‐term potential output growth path, one option is to increase the pre‐crisis trend calculation period in order to capture mostly “normal” years. An alternative is to exclude a certain period prior to the onset of a crisis. Last, the Hodrick–Prescot (HP) filter can be applied to diminish the influence of booms or recessions on the potential growth path. While Aziz et al. (2000) base potential output on the average output of the three years prior to crises, Bordo et al. (2001) use five‐year pre‐crisis growth rates and Hoggarth et al. (2002) calculate potential output trends based on ten‐, three‐, and one‐year pre‐crises growth rates; for a comparative study see Angkinand (2008).

Once we establish the counterfactual, we can estimate total output losses by adding up the difference between actual and potential output over the duration of the respective crisis.

Even though the general concept is agreed upon across the studies mentioned above, several methodological issues remain debated. Identification of crises accompanied by output losses varies among studies. While some authors include a crisis if output is below its trend or if output growth is negative during the crisis year, other studies include crises even though output is above its trend in the crisis year, given that output is below trend in the subsequent year Angkinand (2008). Further issues arise in the case of multiple crises per country within short periods of time. In the case that output has not yet recovered from one crisis at the point of outbreak of a following crisis, some studies choose to sum losses of subsequent crises and report a single loss, while others divide losses across crises or simply choose to exclude countries with multiple crises during the sample period.

2.3Identification of causality

To assess the direction of causality between economic growth and banking crises, Hoggarth et al. (2002) compare a sample of 29 countries experiencing banking crises with neighboring countries which did not face banking crises at the same time. The hypothesis is that “the movement in output relative to trend during the crisis period would have been, in the absence of a banking crisis, the same or similar to the movement in the pairing country”(Hoggarth et al., 2002). Their analysis hints at the point that output losses are in most cases caused by banking crises and come as unforeseen events.

Bordo et al. (2001) find, across all countries and crisis periods considered, that recessions with crises are more severe than recessions without them. These results are in line with various studies such as Frydl (1999).

3Methodology3.1Crisis identification

We use the financial crises dataset of Laeven and Valencia (2008). Currency crises, banking crises, and debt crises are identified over the period 1970–2008. Laeven and Valencia (2008) identify banking crises on the basis of a number of quantitative and subjective criteria, such as a large number of defaults and a high quantity of non‐performing loans. The starting year of a currency crisis is identified by building on an approach developed in Frankel and Rose (1996). Sovereign debt crises are reported in the case of sovereign defaults to private lending as well as in a year of debt rescheduling. The number of currency crises peaked during the early 1980s and the early 1990s with around 30 currency crises per year, while banking crises have in general been less frequent and peaked during the early nineties. The number of debt crises per year has been decreasing since the mid‐1980s and debt crises have nearly ceased to exist until recently, see Bicaba et al. (2011).

We identify the starting date of a financial crisis as the year of outbreak of any one of the three types of crises. Real GDP data is taken from the World Economic Outlook database and spans the time period from 1960 to 2010.

To calculate output losses caused by crises, the first step is to define whether a crisis has an impact on the economy. In the case where output is compared to a counterfactual, we identify a crisis if output in the crisis year is below its trend level (trend output estimations are discussed below). In an alternative calculation of crisis losses, no counterfactual is established and a crisis accompanied by output losses is considered as such if output growth is negative during the crisis year.

For countries with multiple crises during the sample period it is possible that a crisis occurs before the economy has recovered from a previous crisis. In this case, we assign subsequent losses to the later crisis date, establishing a new counterfactual. This method is problematic, though other alternatives suffer from larger errors. Allocating output losses from subsequent crises to the first crisis would largely overstate output losses in various cases.

3.2Output losses

We estimate three kinds of potential output trends and propose several cutoff points to determine the end of a crisis. In short, there is no perfect method to estimate an objective output trend. Every method presented shows both advantages and disadvantages depending on the assumptions about the mechanics of financial crises.

Following the literature, we estimate potential GDP after the onset of a crisis in three ways. We estimate an HP trend, where potential output during a crisis episode is based on the average HP growth rate of the ten and three year pre‐crisis periods. In addition, we use average growth rates from three‐year and ten‐year pre‐crisis time windows. We compare the losses against trend output levels to absolute losses (for episodes with negative growth) without considering opportunity costs. In total we have thirteen possible ways to measure output losses as well as their severity and frequency.

Output losses are calculated as the difference between actual real GDP and its trend level. A graphical example is given in Fig. A.1, depicting output during the Ecuadorian banking crisis, which shows that losses depend not only on the definition of the counterfactual but largely on establishing an end‐point of a crisis.

According to the time output needs to recover its pre‐crisis level, the effects of the crisis lasted two years and led to an output loss of 10% of GDP. If crisis length is calculated until real GDP growth reached its pre‐crisis growth rate, output losses occurred over a period of two and three years and led to output losses of 10.1% and 22.4% of GDP, calculated against a three and ten‐year pre‐crisis growth trend respectively.

As shown in Figs. A.1 and A.2, this calculation most likely still does not account for the total output loss caused by the 1998 Ecuadorian banking crisis. The period of output loss increases to six and seven years, and output losses accumulate to 38.1% and 51.4% of GDP respectively if losses are estimated until the level of real GDP recovers its three and ten‐year pre‐crisis trend. As illustrated in Figs. A.1 and A.2, output losses seem to be underestimated if crisis recovery is defined as being completed at the point where the pre‐crisis growth rate or the pre‐crisis level of real GDP is recovered.

As mentioned above, we estimate losses using various trends and various cut‐off points to determine the end of a crisis. In total, 13 loss estimations are presented.

We distinguish three definitions of recovery from a crisis. According to the first definition, a crisis ends once real output has reached the level of its counterfactual. The alternative is that recovery is completed once the average pre‐crisis growth rate is resumed. As some countries never recover according to these definitions, accumulated losses against the counterfactuals based on linear three and ten‐year trends, based on simple averages of pre‐crises growth, are considered over maximum periods of five and ten years, while the losses against trends based on the HP filter are allowed to accumulate over periods of maximum ten years. Note that an alternative potential remedy that we do not pursue here in cases where we have an infinite sum of losses is to perform present‐value GDP losses by discounting future losses appropriately. In the absence of a counterfactual, a crisis is supposed to be ended once output reaches its absolute pre‐crisis level of real GDP.

4The Loss Distribution Approach

The estimated output losses across countries obtained in the previous section allow us to study the frequency and severity of losses. In the analysis of a financial crisis hitting the world economy, two usual questions appear: (a) what is the frequency of financial crises? and (b) given a financial crisis, how severe is it? The frequency of financial crises is the number of such events over a specific period of time. Since financial crisis duration spans generally more than a year, we choose a five‐year reference period to count financial crises. The severity of a financial crisis is the amount of output loss incurred in each crisis episode.

Given the frequency and severity of losses occurring within 5‐year periods, we can use the LDA common in the insurance and operational risks literature. Chernobai et al. (2011) and Cruz (2004) provide detailed descriptions of the workings of the LDA. We estimate two possible parametric distribution functions commonly used to describe the frequency of events nt over a period of time t. We also estimate a set of six severity probability density functions2 for events zt,i. As contrast to the standard one year period used in the insurance industry or in operational risk capital calculations, our t represents periods of 5 years. This is because GDP losses due to financial crises consider losses over more than one year. The index i tracks each event within the period of analysis t.

During a 5‐year period, global losses are given by the sum of each loss event i across countries in the sample.

The random variable nt takes discrete values while the variables zt,i are non‐negative (positive losses), real valued quantities. The aggregated loss S depends on the realization of the discrete random variable (n) and the continuous random variable (zi). Therefore, the aggregation S is itself a random variable whose distribution has to be determined by convolution methods (Panjer, 2006; Shevchenko, 2011).

Specifically, the frequency of loss events (n) has a probability distribution denoted by pn=Pr(N=n) while the loss severity z has a density distribution and cumulative distribution functions denoted by fz and Fz, respectively. According to Panjer (2006), the cumulative density function of S is defined as:

where FZn(S) is the n‐fold convolution of the cumulative density function of S. A simple way to estimate F(s) is via Monte Carlo simulations. First we draw n from pn and then we draw z from fz as many times as indicated by n. Last, we sum up the z draws.

5Results

In total, we observe 62 debt crises, 122 banking crises, and 196 currency crises. As some of these crises in effect form twin crises, we examine a total of 340 crises episodes. Depending on the method applied, we find between 110 and 219 contractionary crises episodes. While around 210 contractionary crises episodes are identified against HP trends, only 110 crises were accompanied by negative growth rates during the crisis year.

Average losses are higher compared to previous studies. This is so because econometric studies usually estimate losses over a sample comprising recessionary crises as well as crisis followed by a rebound in GDP, while we only consider crises leading to output losses (against a trend or absolute). From a total of 196 currency crises in our sample, between 90 and 120 crises (depending on the calculation method applied) have led to a loss of output compared to some measure of potential output, while 63 crises were accompanied by negative output growth. This result is in line with previous studies such as Gupta et al. (2007), who find that about 60 percent of currency crises lead to output contractions while the rest were accompanied by output expansions.

The analysis that follows concentrates on a benchmark loss classification group that relies on the HP filter: losses until recovering average 10‐year HP filtered GDP growth rates (HP10 perc), the level of a 10‐year HP filtered GDP trend (HP10 trend), 3‐year HP filtered GDP growth rates (HP3 perc), and the level of a 3‐year HP filtered GDP trend (HP3 trend).

5.1The frequency of financial crises

In order to carry out the LDA, we first estimate distribution functions for the frequency of losses from financial crises. We assume two commonly used distributions such as the Poisson and the Negative Binomial Distribution. The key parameter in the Poisson distribution is λ which is also the mean and variance of the number of losses. This is the drawback of the Poisson fit; the data in our benchmark case (the four HP trend counterfactuals) have numbers of crisis events with variances of about sixteen times the mean.3 Therefore, the two‐parameter Negative Binomial distribution is a more flexible way to accommodate our data.

In Fig. A.3 we depict the estimated distributions for our benchmark loss classification. The Negative Binomial distribution has a lower mode but allows a more extreme number of losses relative to the Poisson distribution. The probability that the data come from the Negative Binomial is higher for all cases (the benchmark and all types of loss classifications). In all cases, the mean number of crises occurrence over five‐year periods ranges from 20 to 30.

5.2The severity of financial crises

The average accumulated loss caused by financial crises varies from 9% of real GDP to 15% of real GDP if output losses are accumulated against trends based on HP filtered data (Table 1). In total, depending on the loss measure applied, 186 to 219 crises episodes are observed. Average losses are the largest when calculated against a ten‐year trend and if losses are considered until the level of trend output has been recovered over a maximum time span of 10 years (Tables 2–6).

Table 1.

Severity of financial crises (as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Median  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
HP10 perc  204  0.14  0.06  0.24  0.00  2.30 
HP10 trend  214  0.15  0.07  0.25  0.00  2.30 
HP3 perc  203  0.09  0.05  0.17  0.00  2.04 
HP3 trend  219  0.10  0.06  0.12  0.00  1.06 

Note: Estimation of losses to recover average 10 year HP filtered GDP growth rates (HP10 perc), to recover the level of a 10‐year HP filtered GDP trend (HP10 trend), to recover 3‐year HP filtered GDP growth rates (HP3 perc), and to recover the level of a 3‐year HP filtered GDP trend (HP3 trend).

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 2.

Severity of crises by regions—all crises (Losses as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Nr.  Africa  Nr.  Europe  Nr.  Latin America  Nr.  Asia  Nr.  North. America 
HP10 perc  79  0.13  22  0.17  39  0.10  39  0.20  0.01 
HP10 trend  85  0.13  24  0.18  40  0.12  40  0.22  0.01 
HP3 perc  78  0.07  24  0.10  41  0.12  36  0.10  0.01 
HP3 trend  86  0.08  24  0.14  45  0.08  39  0.12  0.01 

Note: Estimation of losses to recover a 10‐year HP filtered GDP growth (HP10 perc), to recover the level of the 10‐year HP filtered GDP (HP10 trend), to recover a 3‐year HP filtered GDP growth (HP3 perc) and to recover the level of the 3‐year HP filtered GDP (HP3 trend).

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 3.

Severity by income groups (as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Nr.  High income  Nr.  Middle income  Nr.  Low income 
HP10 perc  21  0.13  122  0.18  61  0.11 
HP10 trend  22  0.16  128  0.17  64  0.12 
HP3 perc  22  0.07  120  0.11  61  0.07 
HP3 trend  23  0.09  128  0.11  68  0.07 

Note: Estimation of losses to recover a 10‐year HP filtered GDP growth (HP10 perc), to recover the level of the 10‐year HP filtered GDP (HP10 trend), to recover a 3‐year HP filtered GDP growth (HP3 perc) and to recover the level of the 3‐year HP filtered GDP (HP3 trend).

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 4.

Severity over time—all crises (as percentage of initial GDP).

Period  HP10 perc  HP10trend  HP3 perc  HP3 trend 
1970–75  0.02  0.05  0.02  0.06 
1975–80  0.11  0.14  0.19  0.09 
1980–85  0.18  0.14  0.09  0.10 
1985–90  0.12  0.10  0.06  0.07 
1990–95  0.15  0.16  0.09  0.12 
1995–00  0.19  0.20  0.06  0.07 
2000–05  0.11  0.12  0.07  0.07 

Note: Estimation of losses to recover a 10‐year HP filtered GDP growth (HP10 perc), to recover the level of the 10‐year HP filtered GDP (HP10 trend), to recover a 3‐year HP filtered GDP growth (HP3 perc) and to recover the level of the 3‐year HP filtered GDP (HP3 trend).

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 5.

Features of the PDF of total losses.

  HP10 perc  HP10 trend  HP3 perc  HP3 trend 
99.9% perctl  3.00E+12  3.60E+12  2.40E+12  2.70E+12 
99% perctl  1.70E+12  2.00E+12  1.30E+12  1.50E+12 
Median  1.90E+11  2.20E+11  1.40E+11  1.60E+11 
Mean  3.00E+11  3.60E+11  2.30E+11  2.70E+11 
Std deviation  3.70E+11  4.40E+11  2.90E+11  3.30E+11 

Note: (1) Number of simulations equal to 500000. In all cases, the frequency distribution is the Negative Binomial, the severity PDF is a Weibull. (2) Losses are measured in constant 2005 USD and correspond to five‐year periods.

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 6.

LDA, Losses in constant 2005 USD, over periods of five years, as percentage of 2005 World GDP.

  HP10 perc  HP10 trend  HP3 perc  HP3 trend 
99.9% perctl  6.81%  8.18%  5.45%  6.13% 
99% perctl  3.86%  4.54%  2.95%  3.40% 
Median  0.43%  0.50%  0.31%  0.36% 
Mean  0.68%  0.81%  0.52%  0.61% 

Note: (1) Number of simulations equal to 500 000. In all cases, the frequency distribution is the Negative Binomial, the severity pdf is a Weibull, 2005 World GDP from WDI2006.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Median losses lie between 4.9% and 7.15% of initial GDP and the most severe crises destroy up to three years of economic output.4 This result is in line with studies estimating output losses through alternative approaches, such as Cerra and Saxena (2008).

As can be seen in Table 7 through 14 in Appendix B, alternative estimates of output losses are very heterogeneous. Large average percentage losses are driven by few especially severe crises events. Of these most severe events, potential output has not been reached again within a period of ten years. This result is in line with Furceri and Zdzienicka (2011), who find that the growth rate after debt crises eight years after the onset is still suppressed be nearly 10 percentage points. Amongst the largest losses observed are those of several Asian countries, namely Indonesia in 1998 and Thailand in 1997, both experiencing severe losses in the wake of the Asian crisis.

Table 7.

Losses after financial crises (as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Median  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  186  0.32  0.16  0.44  0.001  2.73 
AG(10)(5)trend  186  0.43  0.24  0.52  0.001  3.62 
AG(3)(5)perc  182  0.32  0.17  0.40  0.000  2.06 
AG(3)(5)trend  186  0.46  0.28  0.57  0.000  4.48 
ABS  110  0.85  0.11  2.21  0.000  16.04 
AG(10)(10)perc  186  0.54  0.16  1.17  0.001  8.27 
AG(10)(10)trend  186  1.06  0.26  1.93  0.001  11.13 
AG(3)(10)perc  180  0.58  0.17  1.27  0.000  9.20 
AG(3)(10)trend  181  0.99  0.34  1.61  0.000  9.20 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 8.

Losses after currency crises (as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  101  0.28  0.39  0.001  1.845 
AG(10)(5)trend  101  0.37  0.49  0.001  2.213 
AG(3)(5)perc  94  0.29  0.37  0.000  1.709 
AG(3)(5)trend  94  0.39  0.43  0.000  1.760 
HP(10)perc  118  0.14  0.28  0.000  2.299 
HP(10)trend  122  0.16  0.29  0.000  2.299 
HP(3)perc  114  0.09  0.21  0.001  2.037 
HP(3)trend  125  0.09  0.13  0.001  1.063 
ABS  61  0.68  1.47  0.000  7.066 
AG(10)(10)perc  101  0.37  0.77  0.001  6.26 
AG(10)(10)trend  101  0.86  1.82  0.001  11.13 
AG(3)(10)perc  94  0.36  0.70  0.000  5.46 
AG(3)(10)trend  94  0.85  1.43  0.000  8.34 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 9.

Losses after banking crises (as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  69  0.37  0.46  0.003  2.731 
AG(10)(5)trend  69  0.48  0.57  0.003  3.616 
AG(3)(5)perc  71  0.33  0.39  0.005  2.062 
AG(3)(5)trend  71  0.48  0.65  0.005  4.484 
HP(10)perc  66  0.14  0.19  0.001  1.277 
HP(10)trend  71  0.15  0.21  0.001  1.308 
HP(3)perc  70  0.08  0.08  0.000  0.471 
HP(3)trend  74  0.10  0.11  0.000  0.757 
ABS  35  0.76  2.16  0.000  12.594 
AG(10)(10)perc  69  0.76  1.57  0.003  8.27 
AG(10)(10)trend  69  1.52  2.47  0.003  11.13 
AG(3)(10)perc  69  0.79  1.72  0.005  9.20 
AG(3)(10)trend  70  1.71  4.78  0.005  9.20 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 10.

Losses after debt crises (as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  39  0.50  0.48  0.001  1.695 
AG(10)(5)trend  39  0.62  0.48  0.001  1.695 
AG(3)(5)perc  39  0.43  0.40  0.001  1.802 
AG(3)(5)trend  39  0.52  0.45  0.001  1.802 
HP(10)perc  46  0.17  0.14  0.021  0.553 
HP(10)trend  47  0.20  0.16  0.006  0.710 
HP(3)perc  43  0.12  0.11  0.009  0.485 
HP(3)trend  45  0.14  0.11  0.003  0.485 
ABS  36  0.87  2.73  0.003  16.038 
AG(10)(10)perc  39  1.66  0.82  0.001  4.039 
AG(10)(10)trend  39  1.82  2.86  0.001  11.134 
AG(3)(10)perc  39  0.63  0.95  0.001  4.605 
AG(3)(10)trend  39  1.13  1.49  0.001  5.708 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 11.

Losses after twin crises—currency and debt (as percentage of initial GDP.

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  56  0.40  0.42  0.001  1.845 
AG(10)(5)trend  56  0.53  0.51  0.001  2.213 
AG(3)(5)perc  52  0.38  0.42  0.001  1.802 
AG(3)(5)trend  52  0.52  0.48  0.001  1.802 
HP(10)perc  64  0.13  0.12  0.002  0.517 
HP(10)trend  67  0.16  0.15  0.002  0.710 
HP(3)perc  66  0.12  0.25  0.002  2.037 
HP(3)trend  71  0.10  0.10  0.002  0.485 
ABS  42  0.54  1.25  0.003  7.066 
AG(10)(10)perc  56  0.57  0.97  0.001  6.26 
AG(10)(10)trend  56  1.40  2.55  0.001  11.13 
AG(3)(10)perc  52  0.53  0.94  0.001  5.46 
AG(3)(10)trend  52  1.08  1.35  0.001  4.75 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 12.

Losses after twin crises—currency and banking (as percentage of initial GDP.

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  78  0.27  0.37  0.001  1.695 
AG(10)(5)trend  78  0.34  0.44  0.001  1.695 
AG(3)(5)perc  73  0.30  0.34  0.001  1.802 
AG(3)(5)trend  73  0.39  0.39  0.001  1.802 
HP(10)perc  101  0.15  0.30  0.002  2.299 
HP(10)trend  103  0.17  0.31  0.002  2.299 
HP(3)perc  95  0.08  0.11  0.001  0.854 
HP(3)trend  103  0.10  0.13  0.001  1.063 
ABS  56  0.65  1.33  0.000  6.826 
AG(10)(10)perc  78  0.31  0.45  0.001  2.19 
AG(10)(10)trend  78  0.87  2.11  0.001  11.13 
AG(3)(10)perc  73  0.35  0.54  0.001  3.71 
AG(3)(10)trend  73  0.72  1.13  0.001  5.71 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 13.

Losses after twin crises—debt and banking (as percentage of initial GDP.

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  36  0.52  0.50  0.001  1.69 
AG(10)(5)trend  36  0.66  0.50  0.001  1.69 
AG(3)(5)perc  35  0.42  0.39  0.001  1.80 
AG(3)(5)trend  35  0.56  0.41  0.001  1.80 
HP(10)perc  32  0.24  0.24  0.009  1.28 
HP(10)trend  34  0.26  0.26  0.006  1.31 
HP(3)perc  32  0.15  0.13  0.000  0.48 
HP(3)trend  33  0.18  0.16  0.000  0.76 
ABS  26  1.18  3.17  0.006  16.04 
AG(10)(10)perc  36  0.80  1.16  0.001  5.47 
AG(10)(10)trend  36  1.76  2.64  0.001  11.13 
AG(3)(10)perc  34  0.82  1.70  0.001  9.20 
AG(3)(10)trend  35  1.33  1.96  0.001  9.20 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 14.

Losses after all twin crises (as percentage of initial GDP).

Loss measure  Obs.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max 
AG(10)(5)perc  114  0.32  0.41  0.001  1.84 
AG(10)(5)trend  114  0.42  0.49  0.001  2.21 
AG(3)(5)perc  105  0.33  0.38  0.001  1.80 
AG(3)(5)trend  105  0.45  0.44  0.001  1.80 
HP(10)perc  130  0.16  0.29  0.002  2.30 
HP(10)trend  136  0.18  0.30  0.002  2.30 
HP(3)perc  126  0.11  0.21  0.000  2.04 
HP(3)trend  136  0.11  0.14  0.000  1.06 
ABS  78  0.90  2.23  0.000  16.04 
AG(10)(10)perc  114  0.47  0.95  0.001  6.26 
AG(10)(10)trend  114  0.99  2.00  0.001  11.13 
AG(3)(10)perc  104  0.53  1.19  0.001  9.20 
AG(3)(10)trend  105  0.98  1.54  0.001  9.20 
Source: Authors’ calculations.

Severity data due to financial crisis have a key feature, it is extreme valued. In Fig. A.4 we see that the mean‐excess‐over‐threshold plots5 have positive slope at the right extreme of losses. Fig. A.4 shows that the long‐tailed nature of severity data is generated by specific types of crises. Currency and twin currency‐banking crises produce the more extreme type of losses (Tables 15–19).

Table 15.

Severity of crises by regions—all crises (losses as percentage of initial GDP).

Variable  Nr.  Africa  Nr.  Europe  Nr.  Latin A.  Nr.  Asia  Nr.  North A. 
AG(10)(5)perc  71  0.25  21  0.47  37  0.28  32  0.51  0.01 
AG(10)(5)trend  71  0.33  21  0.60  37  0.39  32  0.58  0.01 
AG(3)(5)perc  62  0.23  26  0.41  35  0.31  32  0.51  0.04 
AG(3)(5)trend  62  0.31  26  0.53  35  0.42  32  0.69  0.04 
ABS  43  0.78  17  1.23  21  0.31  14  1.41  0.00 
AG(10)(10)perc  71  0.43  21  0.54  37  0.31  32  1.06  0.01 
AG(10)(10)trend  71  0.92  21  1.06  37  0.76  32  1.84  0.01 
AG(3)(10)perc  60  0.34  26  0.58  35  0.38  32  1.16  0.04 
AG(3)(10)trend  61  0.64  26  1.27  35  0.65  32  1.61  0.04 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 16.

Average severity of crises by income groups (percentage of initial GDP).

Variable  Nr.  High income  Nr.  Middle income  Nr.  Low income 
AG(10)(5)perc  21  0.28  112  0.38  53  0.22 
AG(10)(5)trend  21  0.39  112  0.49  53  0.29 
AG(3)(5)perc  21  0.24  113  0.38  48  0.23 
AG(3)(5)trend  21  0.49  113  0.49  48  0.29 
ABS  10  0.44  71  0.79  29  1.13 
AG(10)(10)perc  21  0.40  112  0.67  53  0.34 
AG(10)(10)trend  21  1.07  112  1.19  53  0.77 
AG(3)(10)perc  21  0.43  112  0.68  47  0.41 
AG(3)(10)trend  21  1.10  113  1.07  47  0.75 
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 17.

Average features of the PDF of total losses (more cases).

  ABS  AG10.10 perc  AG10.10 trend  AG3.10 perc  AG3.10 trend 
99.9 percentile  5.70E+12  1.80E+13  3.70E+13  2.20E+13  4.70E+13 
99 percentile  2.70E+12  8.70E+12  1.70E+13  1.10E+13  2.20E+13 
Median  1.80E+11  6.40E+11  1.20E+12  8.10E+11  1.60E+12 
Mean  3.80E+11  1.30E+12  2.40E+12  1.60E+12  3.10E+12 
Std. deviation  6.00E+11  1.90E+12  3.80E+12  2.30E+12  4.80E+12 

Note: (1) Number of simulations equal to 500000. In all cases, the frequency distribution is the Negative Binomial, the severity pdf is a Weibull. (2) Losses are measured in constant 2005 USD and correspond to five‐year periods.

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 18.

Average features of the PDF of total losses (more cases).

Variable  AG10.5 perc  AG10.5 trend  AG3.5 perc  AG3.5 trend 
99.9 percentile  8.80E+12  1.20E+13  1.10E+13  1.50E+13 
99 percentile  4.50E+12  6.20E+12  5.40E+12  7.80E+12 
Median  4.00E+11  5.40E+11  4.90E+11  6.90E+11 
Mean  7.30E+11  9.80E+11  8.60E+11  1.20E+12 
Std. deviation  9.80E+11  1.30E+12  1.20E+12  1.70E+12 

Note: (1) Number of simulations equal to 500000. In all cases, the frequency distribution is the Negative Binomial, the severity pdf is a Weibull. (2) Losses are measured in constant 2005 USD and correspond to five‐year periods.

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 19.

USA 2007 banking crisis losses (percentage of 2007 real GDP).

Loss measure  in billion USD  % of 2007 GDP 
HP(10)(10)perc  3009.28  22.78 
HP(10)(10)trend  14027.90  106.22 
HP(3)(10)perc  2014.14  15.25 
HP(3)(10)trend  7415.09  56.14 
HP(3)(5) trend  4043.20  30.61 
HP(3)(5) perc  2014.14  15.25 
HP(10)(5)trend  6329.73  47.92 
HP(10)(5)perc  3009.28  22.78 
AG(10)(5)perc  5923.15  44.85 
AG(10)(5)trend  5923.15  44.85 
AG(3)perc  5552.58  42.04 
AG(3)trend  5552.58  42.04 
AG(10)(10)perc  15334.18  116.11 
AG(10)(10)trend  17874.42  135.34 
AG(3)(10)perc  9700.10  73.45 
AG(3)(10)trend  17851.69  135.17 
ABS  666.10  5.04 
Source: Authors’ calculations.

We fit the severity data with six possible probability density functions using the maximum likelihood estimator for the corresponding parameters. The six distributions are Gamma, Exponential, Generalized Extreme Value (GEV), Generalized Pareto, Log‐normal, and Weibull. Some distributions, like the GEV, fit the right end tail better, while others have a better fit over the entire range of data. Our benchmark choice is the Weibull distribution because it maintains a better fit over the entire range of data for all severity classifications.

5.2.1Types of financial crises

Consistent with studies like Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), we find that currency crises lead to smaller output losses than debt and banking crises.6 About 70 of the 122 banking crises in our sample lead to output losses. We cannot conclude that banking and currency crises are generally preceded by high or low periods of growth as we do not observe a general dominance of losses calculated against three year pre‐crisis trends as opposed to losses against ten‐year pre‐crisis trends.

We find that average output losses after debt crises7 are 9% higher than losses after banking crises. The median debt crisis is accompanied by output losses of 11.7%, three percentage points larger than the median banking crisis. A large share of debt crises has, however, been accompanied by banking crises. Of the 62 debt crises in our sample, 36 have led to periods of negative growth. Of these 36 episodes, 26 have been accompanied by banking crises with mean losses about 30% higher than if debt crises occur alone. Currency crises8 incur smaller losses than banking or debt crises of 15% in the mean and 5% in the median. This result is in line with Furceri and Zdzienicka (2011) who concluded that debt crises tend to be more detrimental than banking and currency crises.

Banking and debt crises alone are more severe than twin crises consisting of banking and currency crises or debt and currency crises. While twin crises between banking or debt and currency crises mostly lead to larger growth reductions in the very short run than banking or debt crises alone, long term losses are often found to be smaller. A possible explanation could be that depreciation in the wake of a twin crisis (including a currency crisis) allows for a competitiveness gain which is not present when a banking crisis occurs alone and allows for a faster recovery. Twin crises consisting of debt and banking crises consequently incur the highest losses in our sample.9

5.2.2Severity by region

The highest losses after financial crises are experienced in Asia with average losses ranging from 9.8% to 21.8% of initial GDP.10 The second highest losses are observed in Europe, followed by Latin America and Africa. The highest frequency of financial crises is, however, observed in Africa. Europe and Asia are mostly struck by currency and banking crises, while Africa and Latin America have suffered from all three types of crises to nearly equal degrees. In a joint analysis, debt crises were observed to be more severe than currency or banking crises. This result holds for all regions except for Asia, where banking crises lead to the most severe losses. Since a high share of currency and banking crises reported are in effect twin crises, it is however difficult to disentangle losses from both types separately. Furceri and Zdzienicka (2011) confirm our results by controlling for other types of crises.

5.2.3Severity by income groups

In order to compare losses across different income groups, we classify countries into low, middle, and high income categories.11 On average, middle income countries experience the highest output losses (15%), followed by high and low income countries (12% and 11% of initial GDP respectively, see Table 3). This observation holds for currency and banking crises, while losses from debt crises are almost exclusively observed in low and middle income countries.

The median crisis is more severe in high income than middle income countries. High average losses in middle income countries are driven by some extreme crisis events, such as Thailand in 1998, experiencing losses of 229%.12 The median loss is 9% for high income countries, 7% for middle income countries, and 4% for low income countries. In total, middle income countries suffer more from financial crises than high income countries as they experience a larger number of crises per country over the period observed.

5.2.4Severity of financial crises over time

As expected, financial crises were especially harmful during the 1990s and depict the lowest losses during the 1970s and the period after the year 2000. However, this does not necessarily mean that financial crises have become smaller in magnitude.

5.2.5The severity of the 2007 financial crisis in the USA

Our main analysis considers a sample ending in 2005. However, we have enough information to estimate the severity of the 2007 financial crisis in the USA. We date the US banking crisis to late 2007 even though the main event, Lehman Brothers filing for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection, did not take place until September 2008. Output trends are calculated as before with 2007 being the first year of output gap calculations. Data are taken from the IMF World Economic Outlook database until 2011. From 2012 until 2016, real GDP forecasts reported in the IMF database are used. Reliable output losses can therefore only be calculated over an interval of 5 years (2007–2011), larger loss windows are however reported for comparative reasons.

Fig. A.5 in Appendix A shows real GDP for the USA from 1995 until 2016. Average real GDP growth in the ten years prior the financial crisis was 3.2 percent and 3.1 percent in the last three years before 2007. Real GDP growth slowed down to less than 2 percent in 2007 and finally turned negative during 2008 and 2009.

If the costs from the financial crisis are to be considered until the pre‐crisis level of real GDP has been reached again and opportunity costs are ignored, the endpoint of the crisis is found to be in 2011 and costs remain modest at 5% of 2007 real GDP.

Turning toward our baseline calculations, calculated against a linear trend based on a pre‐crisis time window of a HP filtered real GDP series, costs become larger and range between 15% and 48% of initial GDP if a 5‐year time is considered and between 15% and 107% if costs are allowed to accumulate for up to ten years. The windows vary from a three‐year period, if the crisis is considered to be overcome once the pre‐crisis average growth rate is recovered, to ten years in the case of defining the end of a crisis as recovery of the pre‐crisis growth trend.

Baseline results over 5 year windows of around 30% of GDP are consistent with costs calculated in e.g. Chinn and Frieden (2011), who estimate costs of the 2011 financial crisis at 3.5 trillion USD, which is roughly 26% of 2007 real GDP.

Historically, the 2007 financial crisis ranks among the most severe crises episodes. A comparable percentage loss of real GDP during the last 40 years has only been experienced by some Asian countries in the wake of the 1998 Asian crisis.

5.3The distribution of total losses

Given our choice of the frequency distribution and the severity probability density function, we perform Monte Carlo simulations to obtain a numerical probability density function (PDF) of total losses over five years. These PDFs are markedly skewed to the right. Table 5 summarizes the results. The 99.9 percentile of the total loss distribution ranges from 2.4 to 3.6 trillion of 2005 USD. Estimates of cumulative world GDP loss due to the 2008–2009 world financial crisis are 5 trillion (IMF, 2009). This means that the recent financial crisis losses occur with very low probability. For the USA, Chinn and Frieden (2011) estimate a cumulative GDP loss for the USA to be about 3.5 trillion in 2005 USD.

6Risk‐sharing against financial crises

Can output losses from financial crises be diminished or crises prevented ex ante through an insurance scheme against rollover risk or capital flight? As financial crises are relatively rare events, one could imagine countries paying a certain amount of premium during financially stable times and in return having access to these funds during times of need.

Papers like Caballero (2003) and Cordella and Yeyati (2005, 2006) have proposed insurance schemes with global scope. The estimation of the stochastic properties of financial crisis losses at the global perspective in terms of frequency, severity and their global aggregation is a useful device in thinking about the proposed insurance schemes.

According to our estimates, the potential worldwide costs from financial crises over periods of 5 years in percentage terms of 2005 world GDP are presented in Table 6. Average costs of financial crises during a period a five years are relatively small and amount to less than one percent of 2005 world GDP. A period of extreme crisis events, occurring with a one percent probability, produces output costs of up to 4.54% of World GDP. For example, if there is a will to cover global losses up to the 99 percentile, the amount of insurance coverage is such percentile minus the median value.

Many of the debt crises included in the above calculations are in fact destabilizing confidence crises or liquidity crises, during which rollover costs of debt become excessively high, rendering an illiquid country insolvent. In a similar manner, liquidity risk is often the cause for the occurrence of banking crises. The IMF provides a de facto insurance (see Cordella and Yeyati, 2006) for these cases in the form of standard IMF programs. While the IMF does play the role of lender of last resort, it does so ex‐post, after the country usually has already entered into financial turmoil.

As a type of national insurance against crises, nearly all emerging economies have accumulated large amounts of international reserves in order to possess a buffer against pro‐cyclical international capital flows. Caballero (2003) argues that hedging the financial mechanism behind macroeconomic disasters is a problem of a magnitude larger than a single market can handle.

The moral hazard problem arising through a potential insurance scheme is addressed in various studies. Cordella and Yeyati (2005) examine to what degree the presence of a country insurance scheme affects the policymakers’ incentives to undertake reforms. An important channel through which insurance can foster reforms can be identified: Insurance reduces the probability that deteriorating fundamentals evolve into large crises, which may enhance the expected political reforms and increase reform incentives.

Participation in a potential crisis insurance fund would therefore have to be subject to ex ante compliance with a number of clearly defined eligibility criteria, such as low budget deficits and a clear debt to GDP threshold. The potential insurance coverage must be forfeited as soon as the country does not fulfil all criteria. As stated in Cordella and Yeyati (2006), it would also be crucial to characterize and standardize the procedures followed after funds from the insurance facility have been accessed. In the optimal case, the existence of this insurance would incite fiscal discipline and, at the same time, provide liquidity if needed which in turn would lead to fewer crises.

Attractiveness of interest rate insurance implies that the insurance premium in tranquil times is lower than the costs through high rollover costs in turbulent times. In addition, the countries not experiencing liquidity problems have to be assured a benefit from the other country not entering into a crisis which exceeds the costs incurred through the insurance premium. Contrary to regular insurance, risk sharing depends on the contagion effects of financial crises from the country in financial turmoil to the liquid countries. Feasibility and benefit analysis is a potentially attractive area for future research.

7Conclusion

Through the use of the financial crises database of Laeven and Valencia (2008) to date financial crises, we characterize the heterogeneity of aggregate output losses. In our LDA setup, the number of crisis events over a certain period is called the frequency of events, while the different metrics of GDP losses describe the severity of such losses. We fit common parametric frequency and severity distributions to compound global GDP loss densities and to report standard risk measures.

In line with the existing literature, we find that output losses after financial crises are strongly heterogeneous and a large number of countries never recover their pre‐crises growth rates or trends. Loss distributions are skewed to the right, with average losses ranging between 9% and 15% of initial GDP.

Currency crises lead to smaller output losses than debt and banking crises, while the largest losses are found after debt crises. The presence of a debt crisis also exacerbates any of the other two forms of crises, while the presence of a currency crisis in the wake of a debt or banking crisis diminishes output losses through faster recovery. Banking and debt crises alone are found to be more severe than twin crises consisting of banking and currency crises or debt and currency crises.

We compare output costs from financial crises over world regions, country‐income groups, and time. We find that Asia has suffered from the most severe financial crises, while Africa experiences the highest frequency of financial crises. Congruently, middle income countries experience the highest output losses, followed by high and low income countries. Financial crises are observed to have been especially harmful during the 1990s, while a global assessment of the severity of the recent 2008 financial crisis cannot yet be undertaken with our approach.

The LDA approach leads us to conclude that mean worldwide costs of financial crises within periods of 5 years are in the range of 0.5–0.7% of 2005 world GDP. Extreme crises episodes, occurring with a probability of one percent, can lead to losses in the range of 2.95–4.54% of world GDP.

There are some aspects that go beyond the scope of this paper. For example, the treatment of the appropriate time span for the LDA planning. We consider a five‐year horizon but this is not necessarily the best from an optimal insurance design perspective. Also, all the calculations are based on aggregating GDP levels in comparable Dollar units. All calculations regarding percentage GDP losses are made after the LDA aggregation and relative to an initial GDP level. There is a possibility of exploring the LDA benchmark by allowing for the aggregation of percentage GDP losses directly. In this case, suitable GDP weights have to be considered. In addition, financial crisis distort long run growth in a number of cases, if so, losses in terms of GDP per capita instead of GDP levels can provide an adequate long run picture. Last, our loss approach is unconditional but the framework can be extended to incorporate conditioning factors in the stochastic processes that drive frequency and severity of GDP losses. We leave these issues open for future research.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to two anonymous referees, FabrizioOrrego, FabrizioCoricelli, participants at the Central Bank of Peru Annual Conference Encuentro de Economistas2011, Centre of European Studies Annual International Conference, XIII Conference in International Economics of the Spanish Association of International Economics and Finance and the University of Granada, of the Paris School of Economics Macro Workshop and research seminars at both the Central Bank of Peru and the Economics Department at PUCP for very helpful comments.

Appendix A

Figs. A.1–A.5.

Figure A.1.

Percentage loss distributions. Currency, debt and banking crises.

(0.08MB).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure A.2.

Percentage loss distributions over income groups.

(0.07MB).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure A.3.

Percentage loss distributions over regions.

(0.07MB).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure A.4.

Percentage loss distributions over time.

(0.09MB).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure A.5.

Impact of the 2007 financial crisis on US growth.

(0.09MB).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
References
[Aziz et al., 2000]
J. Aziz, F. Caramazza, R. Salgado.
Currency Crises: In Search of Common Elements, IMF Working Paper No. 00/67.
International Monetary Fund, (2000),
[Angkinand, 2008]
Angkinand, A.P., 2008. Output Loss and Recovery from Banking and Currency Crises: Estimation Issues. Manuscript.
[Barro, 2001]
R. Barro.
Economic Growth in East Asia before and after the Financial Crises, NBER Working Paper 8330.
National Bureau of Economic Research, (2001),
[Barro, 2006]
R. Barro.
Rare disasters and asset markets in the twentieth century.
Q. J. Econ., 121 (2006), pp. 823-866
[Bicaba et al., 2011]
Z. Bicaba, D. Kapp, F. Molteni.
Stability periods between Financial crises: the role of macroeconomic fundamentals and crises management policies, CES Working Paper 2011.64.
(2011),
[Bordo et al., 2001]
M. Bordo, B. Eichengreen, D. Klingebiel, M.S. Martinez-Peria.
Is the crisis problem growing more severe?.
Econ. Policy, 16 (2001), pp. 51-82
[Borio et al., 1994]
C. Borio, N. Kennedy, S.D. Prowse.
Exploring aggregate asset price fluctuations across countries: measurement, determinants and monetary policy implications, BIS Economic Papers, 40.
Bank for International Settlements, (1994),
[Boyd et al., 2000]
Boyd, J., Gomis, P., Kwak, S., Smith, B., 2000. A User's Guide to Banking Crises. Manuscript.
[Boyd et al., 2005]
J. Boyd, S. Kwak, B. Smith.
The real output losses associated with modern banking crises.
J. Money Credit Bank., 37 (2005), pp. 977-999
[Caballero, 2003]
R. Caballero.
The future of the IMF.
Am. Econ. Rev., 93 (2003), pp. 31-38
[Caprio and Klingebiel, 1996]
G. Caprio, D. Klingebiel.
Bank Insolvencies. Cross‐country Experience, Policy Research Working Paper No. 1620.
The World Bank, (1996),
[Cecchetti et al., 2009]
S. Cecchetti, M. Kholer, C. Upper.
Financial Crises and Economic Activity, NBER Working Paper No. 15379.
National Bureau for Economic Research, (2009),
[Cerra and Saxena, 2008]
V. Cerra, S.C. Saxena.
Growth dynamics: the myth of economic recovery.
Am. Econ. Rev., 98 (2008), pp. 439-457
[Chernobai et al., 2011]
Chernobai, A., Rachev, S., Fabozzi, F., 2011. Operational Risk: A Guide to Basel II Capital Requirements, Models, and Analysis. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., Hoboken, NJ, United States of America.
[Chinn and Frieden, 2011]
Chinn, M., Frieden, J., 2011. Lost Decades: The Making of American Debt Crisis and Recovery. W.W. Norton & Company, Inc., New York, NY, United States of America.
[Cordella and Yeyati, 2005]
T. Cordella, E.L. Yeyati.
Country Insurance, IMF Staff Paper, 52.
International Monetary Fund, (2005),
[Cordella and Yeyati, 2006]
T. Cordella, E.L. Yeyati.
A (new) country insurance facility.
Int. Finance, 9 (2006), pp. 1-36
[Cruz, 2004]
M. Cruz.
Operational Risk Modeling and Analysis: Theory and Practice.
Risk Books, (2004),
[Demirguc‐Kunt and Detragiache, 1998]
A. Demirguc-Kunt, E. Detragiache.
The determinants of banking crises in developing and developed countries.
IMF Staff Papers, 45 (1998), pp. 81-109
[Demirguc‐Kunt et al., 2006]
A. Demirguc-Kunt, E. Detragiache, P. Gupta.
Inside the crisis: an empirical analysis of banking systems in distress.
J. Int. Money Finance, 25 (2006), pp. 702-718
[Furceri and Zdzienicka, 2011]
D. Furceri, D. Zdzienicka.
How Costly Are Debt Crises? IMF Working Paper No. 11/280.
International Monetary Fund, (2011),
[Frankel and Rose, 1996]
J. Frankel, A. Rose.
Currency crashes in emerging markets: an empirical treatment.
J. Int. Econ., 41 (1996), pp. 351-366
[Frydl, 1999]
E. Frydl.
The Length and Cost of Banking Crises, IMF Working Paper No. 99/30.
International Monetary Fund, (1999),
[Gorton, 1988]
G. Gorton.
Banking Panics and Business Cycles.
Oxford Econ. Papers, 40 (1988), pp. 221-255
[Gupta et al., 2007]
P. Gupta, D. Mishra, R. Sahay.
Behavior of output during currency crises.
J. Int. Econ., 72 (2007), pp. 428-450
[Hanna and Huang, 2002]
D. Hanna, Y. Huang.
Bank restructuring in post‐crisis Asia.
Asian Econ. Papers, 1 (2002), pp. 3-42
[Hoggarth et al., 2002]
G. Hoggarth, R. Reis, V. Saporta.
Costs of banking system instability: some empirical evidence.
J. Bank. Finance, 26 (2002), pp. 825-855
[IMF, 2009]
IMF, 2009. Global Financial Stability Report. November 2009 update. International Monetary Fund.
[Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999]
G. Kaminsky, C. Reinhart.
The twin crises: the causes of banking and balance‐of‐payments problems.
Am. Econ. Rev., 89 (1999), pp. 473-500
[Kindleberger, 1978]
C. Kindleberger.
Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises.
Palgrave Macmillan, (1978),
[Laeven and Valencia, 2008]
L. Laeven, F. Valencia.
Systemic Banking Crises: A New Database, IMF Working Paper No. 08/224.
International Monetary Fund, (2008),
[Lindgren et al., 1996]
C. Lindgren, G. Garcia, M. Saal.
Bank Soundness and Macroeconomic Policy.
International Monetary Fund, (1996),
[Logan, 2001]
A. Logan.
The United Kingdom's small banks’ crisis of the early 1990s: what were the leading indicators of failure? Bank of England Working Paper No. 139.
Bank of England, (2001),
[Panjer, 2006]
H. Panjer.
Operational Risk: Modeling Analytics.
Wiley, (2006),
[Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009]
C. Reinhart, K. Rogoff.
This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly.
Princeton University Press, (2009),
[Shevchenko, 2011]
P. Shevchenko.
Modelling Operational Risk Using Bayesian Inference.
Springer, (2011),

Sometimes an additional criterion of increased speed of depreciation as compared to some prior time window is introduced.

The set is composed of the gamma, exponential, generalized extreme value, generalized pareto, log normal and weibull density functions.

The number of crisis events for the other loss classifications have a variance to mean ratio of more than 13, except for the case where opportunity costs are not considered (ABS).

Crises’ percentage losses are calculated as the sum of the difference between real output observed and potential output after the onset of a crisis until its end, divided by the real output in the year of crisis onset. Losses are usually larger if calculated on the basis of other trend estimations as presented in the appendix.

The sample mean excess plot is defined by: ∑inX1−uIXi>u/∑inIXi>u, with u>0 and I(.) and indicator function.

Distributions of these three types of crises’ losses, calculated as losses accrued over a maximum period of five years until the average growth rate of a 10‐year pre‐crises period is recovered, are depicted in Fig. A.5, while descriptive statistics of all calculation methods are provided in Tables 8–14.

23% of initial GDP if recovery of the average HP growth rate ten years before a crisis is considered (HP10 perc).

According to HP10 perc.

For detailed descriptive statistics of other loss measures, please see Tables 8–14.

Calculated against counterfactuals based on average HP filtered growth rates.

World Bank classification.

Copyright © 2012. Asociación Cuadernos de Economía
Descargar PDF
Opciones de artículo