covid
Buscar en
Investigaciones Europeas de Dirección y Economía de la Empresa
Toda la web
Inicio Investigaciones Europeas de Dirección y Economía de la Empresa Financial situation and political parties in local governments: Empirical eviden...
Información de la revista
Vol. 20. Núm. 3.
Páginas 110-121 (septiembre - diciembre 2014)
Compartir
Compartir
Descargar PDF
Más opciones de artículo
Visitas
2632
Vol. 20. Núm. 3.
Páginas 110-121 (septiembre - diciembre 2014)
Open Access
Financial situation and political parties in local governments: Empirical evidence in the Spanish municipalities
Situación financiera y partidos políticos en los gobiernos locales: evidencia empírica en los municipios españoles
Visitas
2632
Roberto Cabaleiro Casala,
Autor para correspondencia
rcab@uvigo.es

Corresponding author.
, Enrique J. Buch Gómeza, Antonio Vaamonde Listeb
a Department of Financial Economics and Accounting, University of Vigo, Lagoas Marcosende s/n, 36310 Vigo, Spain
b Department of Statistics and Operations Research, University of Vigo, Torrecedeira, 105, 36208 Vigo, Spain
Este artículo ha recibido

Under a Creative Commons license
Información del artículo
Resumen
Texto completo
Bibliografía
Descargar PDF
Estadísticas
Figuras (1)
Tablas (8)
Table 1. Financial indicators.
Table 2. Political variables.
Table 3. Socieconomic variables.
Table 4. Process of factor analysis.
Table 5. Tests of between-subjects effects.
Table 6. Pairwise comparisons. Dependent variables FG1_1 and FG5_1.
Table 7. Pairwise comparisons. Dependent variable FG4_1.
Table 8. Pairwise comparisons. Dependent variables FG4_1 and FG6_1.
Mostrar másMostrar menos
Abstract

In contrast to several studies presented in the literature which analyze how different political elements affect specific aspects of financial management of public institutions, we have investigated from a comprehensive perspective how various political factors influence the financial situation of the municipalities. To do this, we use diverse multivariate techniques, the concept of financial condition and a large sample of Spanish municipalities. By isolating the electoral cycle and analyzing the essence of political factors, our main findings are that conservative and progressive parties do not present different behavior in relation to any of the financial dimensions. The territoriality of political parties influences the relationship between fund transfers received by the municipalities and certain expenses and investments. Furthermore, we did not detect that, in Spain, a partisan alignment exists between municipalities and the upper-level institutions.

Keywords:
Local governments
Public finance
Public administration
Political parties
JEL classification:
H70
Resumen

En contraste con los diversos estudios presentes en la literatura que analizan cómo los diferentes elementos políticos afectan a aspectos específicos de la gestión financiera de las instituciones públicas, hemos investigado desde una perspectiva integral cómo varios factores políticos influyen en la situación financiera de los municipios. Para ello hemos usado diversas técnicas multivariantes, el concepto de condición financiera y una amplia muestra de municipios españoles. Aislando el ciclo electoral y analizando la esencia de los factores políticos, nuestros principales hallazgos son que los partidos conservadores y progresistas no presentan distintas conductas en las diferentes dimensiones financieras, y que la territorialidad de los partidos políticos influye en la relación entre los fondos recibidos por transferencias y ciertos gastos e inversiones. Además, no hemos detectado que exista un alineamiento partidista entre los municipios españoles y las instituciones de nivel superior.

Palabras clave:
Gobiernos locales
Finanzas públicas
Administraciones públicas
Partidos políticos
Texto completo
1Introduction

Studies analysing the influence of political factors on specific aspects of financial management of public administrations, as deficit, expenditures, tax burden, revenues, public debt, and transfers at different territorial levels are, numerous (Benito & Bastida, 2010; Poterba, 1994; Rattsø & Tovmo, 2002; Roubini & Sachs, 1989; Solé-Ollé & Sorribas-Navarro, 2008; Veiga & Veiga, 2007).

Unlike these previous studies, García-Sánchez, Mordan, and Prado-Lorenzo (2012) analyzed the effect that political ideology and strength have on overall financial management of local governments through analysis of the financial condition concept in the largest Spanish municipalities. However, this study was limited because they directly assigned indicators to the financial dimensions, and performed individually the political variables on each of the indicators from a limited set. Furthermore, using various indicators which may reflect the same behavior tends to distort the analysis because this promotes the assessment of aspects in a duplicate manner (Cabaleiro, Buch, & Vaamonde, 2012).

Different from the rest of the studies presented in the literature, our paper is based on a more comprehensive vision that eliminates the analysis of redundant financial aspects and it intends to explain how different political factors such as ideology, political weakness of governments, and alignment between political hierarchical institutions (which have not presented conclusive results in previous works), or territoriality of political parties (which have not been empirically verified) may be influencing the overall financial health of local governments.

2Literature review: background and hypotheses2.1The financial health of local governments

Various terms that correspond to different methodological approaches were used in the literature to analyze the same reality, the financial health (Berne, 1992; Clark, 1994; Carmeli, 2003; Kloha, Weissert, & Kleine, 2005; Wang, Dennis, & Tu, 2007), and the financial condition is one of the terms most widely used (Cabaleiro et al., 2012; Rivenbark & Roenigk, 2011; Sohl, Peddle, Thurmaier, Wood, & Kuhn, 2009; Wang et al., 2007). In this sense, Honadle, Costa, and Cigler (2004) noted that financial condition of local institutions is a term closely linked to the concept of fiscal health and Wang et al. (2007) pointed out that this concept represents the ability of an organization to meet its financial obligations on time.

As financial condition is a concept that is not directly observable, literature has focused on assessing the different aspects or dimensions that compose it (Clark, 1977; Groves, Godsey, & Shulman, 1981; Hendrick, 2004; Mercer & Gilbert, 1996). Groves et al. (1981) note that financial condition is composed of cash solvency (government's capacity to generate enough cash or liquidity to pay its bills), budgetary solvency (the city's ability to generate sufficient revenues over its normal budgetary period to meet its expenditure obligations and not incur deficits), long-run solvency (the long-run ability of a government to pay all the costs of doing business, including expenditure obligations that normally appear in each annual budget, as well as those that show up only in the years in which they must be paid), and service-level solvency (it refers to whether a government can provide the level and quality of services required for the general health and welfare of a community), and this approach was assumed by the International City/County Management Association [ICMA] (2003) for its extensive application in local governments in USA.

Another significant contribution for the local level is made by the Canadian Institute of Chartered Accountants [CICA] (1997, 2009) which assesses the concept through the dimensions of sustainability (degree to which a government can maintain its existing financial obligations without increasing the relative debt or tax burden on the economy within which it operates), flexibility (degree to which a government can change its debt or tax burden on the economy within which it operates to meet its existing financial obligations), and vulnerability (degree to which a government is dependent on sources of funding outside its control or influence or is exposed to risks that could impair its ability to meet its existing financial obligations).

To assess the financial condition, numerous indicators have been used. It should be noted that there has not been a common view in their selection, use, and application (CICA, 1997, 2009; Clark, 1977, 1994; Groves et al., 1981; Hendrick, 2004; ICMA, 2003).

On the contrary, the financial condition of governments and socioeconomic variables are interrelated aspects (Carmeli & Cohen, 2001; Honadle et al., 2004). The characteristics of a socioeconomic environment are diverse and varied in nature, that is, the economic sectors, nature of the territory, population structure and population movements, and economic policies developed by state public institutions (Honadle, 2003). In addition, the ICMA (2003) includes among the “environmental factors” the variables of population size, density, the level of unemployment, and business activity. Wang et al. (2007) analyzed the relationship between the financial condition and population (population size and growth rate) and economic factors (personal income per capita, gross state product per capita, and percentage change in personal income), and concluded that these variables can be used to predict the financial condition with a certain level of accuracy.

2.2The political factors on the financial health of local governments

The ICMA (2003) considers that issues of a political nature must also be taken into account among the various factors to consider in the analysis of the financial management of public institutions. Except the limited study of García-Sánchez et al. (2012), there have been no empirical studies evaluating the relationship between the global financial situation of public institutions and political factors, although diverse political factors have been used to predict specific aspects of financial management (Alesina & Perotti, 1995; Alesina & Tabellini, 1990; Ashworth, Geys, & Heyndels, 2005; Benito & Bastida, 2010; Curto-Grau, Solé-Ollé, & Sorribas-Navarro, 2012; Solé-Ollé & Sorribas-Navarro, 2008).

A first political issue that we could not ignore is “The political cycle theory” or “Political opportunism”, which assumes that the primary interest of a politician or party is being re-elected and there are no ideological motives. Franzese (2002) notes that this theory is focused on the impact of the timing of elections, and this causes changes in some financial variables (debt, deficit, expenses, and transfers).

The “partisan theory” attributes central importance to the ideological differences between groups within a society and the parties that represent these groups (Persson & Svensson, 1989; Tuffe, 1978). In this line, unlike the conservative parties, progressives tend to increase public spending, showing greater laxity in public financial management (Tuffe, 1978). However, this theory has not been confirmed empirically in some studies at municipal level as in those made by Bosch and Suarez-Pandiello (1995) and Benito and Bastida (2010).

Some papers have examined the effect of political decentralization on the organization or cohesion of political parties (Desposato, 2004; Wildavsky, 1967). Territorial (local and regional) parties are thought to exist because these geographical areas have unique interests and concerns that cannot be or are not being addressed adequately by existing parties to other level (Brancati, 2008; Hearl, Budge, & Pearson, 1996).

Following the line of study based on “weak government” or “fragmented governments”, Roubini and Sachs (1989) initiated a line of empirical work studying the influence of fragmentation of governments on the finance of public institutions. At the municipal level, the works that researched any aspect of public finances have been few and they have also presented different results (Ashworth et al., 2005; Borge, 2005; Bruce, Carrol, Deskins, & Rork, 2007; Geys, 2007; Goeminne, Geys, & Smolders, 2008; Rattsø & Tovmo, 2002).

Another political factor is based on the “hypothesis of the partisan alignment”. In this context, the research carried out was articulated from different perspectives: “clientelism” (Diaz-Cayeros, Magaloni, & Weingast, 2006; Scheiner, 2005), “perverse accountability” (Stokes, 2005), and the “model of pork barrel” (Brollo & Nannicini, 2010; Solé-Ollé & Sorribas-Navarro, 2008). If there is a partisan alignment between the municipal government and the upper-level government, these entities receive larger fund transfers (Brollo & Nannicini, 2010; Diaz-Cayeros et al., 2006; Solé-Ollé & Sorribas-Navarro, 2008). The effect of a partisan alignment between regional and local governments has been considered in Spain by Solé-Ollé and Sorribas-Navarro (2008) and by Curto-Grau et al. (2012).

2.3Hypotheses

According to the previous arguments, the aim of our study is concretized on the following hypotheses:Hypothesis 1

The ideology of the municipal government affects the dimensions of financial condition of the Spanish municipalities.

Hypothesis 2

The territoriality of political parties of the municipal government affects the dimensions of financial condition of the Spanish municipalities.

Hypothesis 3

The municipal government's weakness affects the dimensions of financial condition of the Spanish municipalities.

Hypothesis 4

The partisan alignment of the municipal government affects the dimensions of financial condition of the Spanish municipalities.

3The financial health and political parties in Spanish local governments3.1Data

The very short data series available having adequate detailed financial information and the necessity to isolate the impact of political cycle on the global financial situation of the municipalities have forced us to use a transversal analysis, and then we chose the year 2009 because of its intermediate position in the electoral cycle of 2007–2011. The financial data for our study were collected from the databases of the “Settlement of the Local Budgets for 2009” and the “Municipal Debt Volume for 2009” (Ministry of Finances and Public Administrations). The data on socioeconomic indicators for 2009 were extracted from the “Municipal Database” of La Caixa and “Inebase” (National Statistics Institute). The information on the political variables was extracted from the “Database of Electoral Results” of the Ministry of Interior and the “Database of Mayors of Legislature 2007–2011” (Ministry of Finances and Public Administrations).

The work is focused on municipalities with more than 20,000 inhabitants and they represent 70% of the population in Spain. After cross-checking all the databases and eliminating municipalities with incomplete and missing data, Madrid and Barcelona because they have a special financial legislation, and Ceuta and Melilla for their different administrative systems, the sample has 387 of 399 municipalities with this population level.

3.2Methodology

The complexity of municipal finances analysis “requires that a mosaic of indicators be employed to account for the multitude of internal and external financial factors that comprise any given community's financial profile” (Sohl et al., 2009). In previous studies, the financial dimensions are measured through the assignment of indicators by the authors, with any exception (Clark, 1977; Mercer & Gilbert, 1996). However, an inconsistent use of indicators diminishes the reliability of a study (Sohl et al., 2009). For this reason, we used a wide set of financial ratios covering the numerous financial aspects or dimensions included in the approaches developed by ICMA (2003) and CICA (1997, 2009) because they are the more institutional relevant frameworks (see Table 1).

Table 1.

Financial indicators.

  Indicator  Description  Min.Max.  MeanStd. D 
R1(CCE+AR-DAR-EF)/OO  Refined short-term solvency: Cash and Cash Equivalents (CCE) plus accounts receivable (AR), less doubtful accounts receivable (DAR) and excess funds to finance expenditures earmarked funding (EF), divided by outstanding obligations (OO) at year end.−1.1296  1.5066 
  11.0873  1.6055 
R2(CCE+AR–DAR)/OO  Gross short-term solvency: Cash and Cash Equivalents (CCE) plus accounts receivable (AR) and less doubtful accounts receivable (DAR), divided by the outstanding obligations (OO) at year end.−0.8021  2.2364 
  13.3634  2.0883 
R3CCE/OO  Quick Ratio: Cash and Cash Equivalents (CCE) divided by outstanding obligations (OO) at year end.−0.8593  1.1921 
  9.1112  1.6058 
R4Long-term debt/TNBR  Long-term debt in relation to the total net budgetary revenues (TNBR)0.0000  0.4574 
  1.2448  0.2433 
R5Long-term debt/NBR Ch.a 1–8  Long-term debt divided by net budgetary revenues (NBR) from non-financial operations.0.0000  0.4887 
  1.3883  0.2657 
R6Long-term debt/NBR Ch. 1–5  Ratio between the long-term debt and net budgetary revenues from current operations.0.0000  0.5851 
  1.9421  0.3221 
R7Long-term debt/Pop.  Long-term debt per inhabitant (Pop)0.0000  521.8737 
  1870.3005  323.2263 
R8NBR Ch. 1–5/NBO Ch. 1–4  Net current budgetary revenues divided by net budget obligations (NBO) from current expenditures0.6062  1.0993 
  1.5524  0.1227 
R9NBR Ch. 1 a 5/NBO Ch. 1–4 and 9  Net current budgetary revenues divided by budget obligations from non-financial current expenditures and debt service.0.5750  1.0502 
  1.4689  0.1229 
R10Net savings/Pop.  Difference between the receivables from current budget resources and the budget obligations from non-financial current expenditures, minus debt service per inhab.−616.8927  24.1831 
  608.4843  123.6380 
R11NBO Ch. 3 and 9/NBR Ch. 1–5  Debt service (interest and principal) divided by net current budgetary revenues0.0000  0.0798 
  0.7883  0.0766 
R12NBO Ch. 3 and 9/Pop.  Debt service per inhabitant.0.0000  70.4389 
  554.4883  64.9648 
R13NBO Ch. 3/Pop.  Debt interest per inhabitant.0.0000  14.9772 
  68.9641  13.0068 
R14RBS/Pop.  Result of the budget settlement (RBS) per inhabitant.−442.3983  −3.8714 
  511.9483  135.5810 
R15Total NBR/Pop.  Total net budgetary revenues per inhabitant.515.9096  1135.235 
  2751.8405  303.1544 
R16NBR Ch. 1–5/NBR Ch. 4  Ratio between net current budgetary revenues and current grants received.1.4400  3.2518 
  8.6505  1.0269 
R17NBR Ch. 1–3/NBO Ch. 1–3  Direct and indirect taxes and fees divided by obligations from net expenditure of personnel, services and debt interest.0.3450  0.7763 
  1.9859  0.1760 
R18NBR Ch. 1–3/NBO Ch. 1–4  Direct and indirect taxes and fees divided by net budget obligations from current expenditures.0.3320  0.7003 
  1.2644  0.1398 
R19NBR Ch. 1–3/Pop.  Direct and indirect taxes and fees per inhabitant.172.2499  576.7365 
  1711.3735  211.6842 
R20NBR Ch. 1 and 3–5/NBO Ch. 1–4  Net current budgetary revenues less current grants received, divided by net budget obligations (NBO) from current expenditures.0.3550  0.7321 
  1.2685  0.1491 
R21NBR Ch. 1–3, 5, 6, 8, 9/Total NBO  Difference between total net budgetary revenues and budgetary current and capital transfers received divided by total net budget obligations.0.2485  0.5994 
  1.1400  0.1307 
R22NBR Ch. 7/Pop.  Capital transfers received per inhabitant23.3007  151.9534 
  566.4735  65.6506 
R23NBR Ch. 4 and 7/Pop.  Current and capital transfers received per inhabitant227.1974  442.9539 
  1011.9293  127.7745 
R24NBO Ch. 6 and 7/Pop.  Investments per inhabitant: Net budget obligations from capital expenditures, capital transfers and capital grants per inhabitant.37.9950  263.1461 
  746.5829  122.8229 
R25NBO Ch. 6 and 7/Total NBO  Investments effort: Net budget obligations from capital expenditures, capital transfers and capital grants divided by total net budget obligations.0.0360  0.2279 
  0.5036  0.0781 
R26NBR Ch. 1 and 2/Pop.  Tax revenues per inhabitant.110.1501  389.6998 
  949.1808  146.7996 
R27NBR Ch. 1, art. 1/Pop.  Capital tax revenues per inhabitant.99.2524  328.5324 
  912.2925  132.5457 
R28NBR Ch. 1, art. 3/Pop.  Economic activity tax revenues per inhabitant.5.2736  31.1589 
  210.9601  26.4245 
R29NBR Ch. 2/Pop.  Indirect tax revenues per inhabitant.1.1352  25.6133 
  227.8817  24.6589 
R30NBR Ch. 3/Pop.  Taxes and public fees for services provided per inhabitant41.8411  187.0366 
  981.4307  102.6173 
R31Politic.Expend.b 13/Pop.  Expenditures on civil protection, public safety, vehicle traffic, and fire protection per inhabitant.4.3280  95.6370 
  269.4893  40.1052 
R32Politic.Expend. 15/Pop.  Expenditures on housing development and urban planning per inhabitant.0.0000  150.9430 
  522.9775  97.3866 
R33Politic.Expend. 16/Pop.  Community welfare spending (Water supply, sewerage and wastewater treatment, municipal waste collection, street cleaning, cemeteries, street lighting) per inhabit.0.0000  163.3166 
  793.1111  82.8298 
R34Politic.Expend. 17/Pop.  Expenditures on environmental protection per inhabitant0.0000  39.5123 
  230.3696  31.0866 
R35Areac Expend. 2/Pop.  Expenditure on social services agency and promoting employment per inhabitant.24.0672  131.1722 
  392.2389  58.4665 
R36Area Expend. 3/Pop.  Expenditure on preferential public service (Health, education, culture and sport) per inhabitant26.4085  209.3143 
  620.2904  98.6590 
R37Area Expend. 4/Pop.  Expenditure on promotion of economic activity per inhabitant0.6357  72.4249 
  539.8732  73.9392 
R38Politic.Expend. 91/Pop.  Expenditure on salaries of political governing per inhabitant0.0000  22.6730 
  102.5483  11.2454 
R39Politic.Expend. 92/Pop.  Expenditure on general services (administrative staff and expenses) per inhabitant0.0000  135.6030 
  736.6846  94.8837 

Valid N (listwise) 387.

a

Chapter of the economic classification of the budgets in Spain.

b

Policy of expenditure on the Planning Programming Budgeting System in Spain.

c

Area of expenditure on the Planning Programming Budgeting System in Spain.

As each indicator may reflect aspects of more than one dimension (Cabaleiro et al., 2012), we will try to associate sets of indicators with similar variability to the dimensions conceptually defined by CICA and ICMA, using a multivariate statistical technique that attempts to overcome the limitations of previous works. In this sense, to assign univocally the ratios to the different financial aspects, we applied a sequential, agglomerative and non-overlapping method (hierarchical clustering with Ward method) based on the minimization of the variance of the dissimilarity measure of the squared Euclidean distance.

On each of the clusters of variables obtained, we applied factor analysis. The purpose is to find in each cluster a small number of uncorrelated aspects that explain the behavior of all the variables of the group with minimum loss of information. Consequently, the financial dimensions or sub-dimensions obtained by regression (dependent variables) are integrated by the groups of indicators that have similar variability, that is, similar behavior (Cabaleiro et al., 2012; Clark, 1977; Mercer & Gilbert, 1996). Each of these blocks/groups was identified in coherence with its information and by taking into account the financial dimensions or sub-dimensions from the ICMA and CICA frameworks.

To analyze how the political variables (ideology, territoriality of political parties, government weakness, and partisan alignment) (Table 2) might affect the dimensions that make up the financial condition of municipalities, we test if mean values are different. To do this, we performed an analysis of variance–covariance.

Table 2.

Political variables.

Political variable  Description  Freq  Relative freq (%) 
(PV1) IdeologyProgressive (1)  204  52.7 
Conservative (2)  151  39.0 
Not defined (3)  32  8.3 
(PV2) Territoriality of political partiesNational (1)  321  82.9 
Regional (2)  46  11.9 
Local (3)  20  5.2 
(PV3) Government weaknessGovernment party with absolute majority (1)  190  49.1 
Government party without absolute majority (0)  197  50.9 
(PV4) Partisan alignment
(PV4_1) ProvincialThe same political party that governs the municipality also governs the province (1)  235  60.7 
The political party that governs the municipality does not govern the province (0)  152  39.3 
(PV4_2) RegionalThe same political party that governs the municipality also governs the Autonomous Community (1)  213  55.0 
The political party that governs the municipality does not govern the Autonomous Community (0)  174  45.0 

Valid N (listwise) 387.

As noted above, socioeconomic factors are configured as elements of contrasted influence. For this reason, we must control the effect of demographic and economic environment variables (Table 3) on the financial condition of the municipalities.

Table 3.

Socieconomic variables.

Socioeconomic variable  Description  Min.  Mean 
    Max.  Std. D 
(SV1) PopulationPopulation of municipality. 2009.20040.00  69250.64 
809267.00  92007.48 
(SV2) ImmigrantsRegistered inhabitants who have no Spanish nationality in the municipality as a percentage of total population. 2009.0.0166  0.1528 
0.7547  0.1083 
(SV3) Population change (2004–2009)Variation of the total number of inhabitants in the municipality between 2004 and 2009 (%)−0.0491  0.0984 
0.5220  0.0940 
(SV4) Immigrants change (2004–2009)Variation of the number of immigrants in the municipality between 2004 and 209 (%)0.0814  0.6073 
2.2511  0.2991 
(SV5) DensityNumber of inhabitants per square kilometer. 2009.25.85  1750.08 
21896.00  2950.26 
(SV6) Unemployment indexNumber of unemployed registered in the Public Employment Service in each municipality in relation to the potentially active population (15–64 years). July 1, 2009.0.0530  0.1328 
0.2630  0.0357 
(SV7) Unemployment evolutionVariation of the number of unemployed registered in the Public Employment Service in each municipality in relation to the potentially active population (15–64 years) between 2004 and 2009 (%)0.2323  1.1616 
5.0714  0.6381 
(SV8) Economic activity indexComparative index of the extent of all economic activity. The index, covering the year 2009, is made by La Caixa (2011) according to the tax (share price) of the economic activity tax for all business and professionals economic activities for estimation and reflects the relative weight of economic activity of the municipality with respect to the total of Spain in base 100,000. The indicator that we use is the index of economic activity of La Caixa multiplied by 100,000 and divided by the population1.5782  18.9674 
243.4437  30.6042 
(SV9) Economic activity evolutionVariation of the economic activity index between 2004 and 2009 (%)−0.4835  −0.0328 
2.0690  0.2312 

Valid N (listwise) 387.

3.3Analysis of results

Following the methodological process described, after typifying all the financial variables (I1 to I39), we performed a cluster analysis of the variables. Fig. 1 shows the dendrogram where six groups of financial ratios (FG1 to FG6) can be clearly identified (see the cut line for rescaled distance=10).

Fig. 1.

Clustering process of financial variables.

(0.31MB).

Following the methodology described, the technique of factor analysis was applied within each one of these groups and has led us to identify the following dependent variables, that is, financial groups (FG) (Table 4):

  • -

    FG1 (R4, R5, R6, R7, R13, R11, and R12): They are basically indicators related to the dimension of long-term solvency. This group has two distinct behaviors or dimensions (factors). The first aspect gives more importance to the indicators related to the volume of debt of the entity (R4, R5, R6, R7, R13) (FG1_1). The second behavior gives more importance to the indicators R1 and R12 and an opposite direction to the other. This refers to the speed with which the entity is to amortize its debt (FG1_2).

  • -

    FG2 (R26, R27, R19, R18, R20, R17, R16, and R21) represents a homogeneous group of indicators essentially concerned with budgetary solvency derived from the entity's ability to generate its own income (FG2_1).

  • -

    FG3 (R28, R36, R31, R34, R38, R29, R15, R30, R33, and R39) basically consists of a set of service ratios and income tax ratios related to economic activity in the municipal environment with similar variability to all local government revenue. This seems to reflect a level of solvency of services of each entity, which is linked to the activity of local economic environment (FG3_1).

  • -

    FG4 (R24, R25, R32, R22, R23, R35, and R37). This group is composed of indicators of transfers, investments, and certain spending policies. This seems to reflect a degree of financial dependence on other institutions to provide certain services and investment. The factor analysis shows the existence of two distinct behaviors or dimensions. The first shows a similar behavior between transfers received and transfers made, the real investments, and housing and urban policies and to a lesser extent, the spending policies of social protection and economic policies (FG4_1). The second component reflects a different behavior of the policies of social protection expenditure and economic policies in relation to investments and transfers made (FG4_2); that is, it displays the extent to which the local entity opts for performing one or other expenses.

  • -

    FG5 (R2, R3, and R1): The group is only composed of indicators of short-term solvency or cash solvency (FG5_1).

  • -

    FG6 (R8, R9, R10, and R14): The group is only composed of indicators of current and overall balanced budget. This represents general budgetary solvency (FG6_1).

Table 4.

Process of factor analysis.

Financial group  FG1FG2FG3FG4FG5FG6
Indicators  R4, R5, R6, R7, R13, R11, and R12R26, R27, R19, R18, R20, R17, R16, and R21R28, R36, R31, R34, R38, R29, R15, R30, R33, and R39R24, R25, R32, R22, R23, R35, and R37R2, R3, and R1R8, R9, R10, and R14
Components
Num.  211211
KMO
Sampl. adequacy  0.6960.9000.7540.6180.7030.790
Bartlett test
Approx. chi-square  4819.2954398.2221017.5771206.3921831.9441704.970
df  2128452136
Sig.  0.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.000
Variance explained (%)  FG1_1: 68.498FG1_2: 19.670FG2_1: 79.653FG3_1: 78.293FG4_1: 44.245FG4_2: 18.910FG5_1: 95.930FG6_1: 80.434
Communalities  R4R5R6R7R13R11R12  0.9570.9560.9440.8790.5010.9600.974  R26R27R19R18R20R17R16R21  0.8040.7780.8120.8320.8310.7540.8240.738  R28R36R31R34R38R29R15R30R33R39  0.0900.2190.1550.0950.1210.0380.9930.5700.3680.113  R24R25R32R22R23R35R37  0.8580.7610.6240.5590.7070.4580.453  R2R3R1  0.9870.9500.921  R8R9R10R14  0.9300.9150.8160.556 
  Extraction method: principal component analysis.
Component matrix
FG1FG2FG3FG4FG5FG6
  FG1_1  FG1_2    FG2_1    FG3_1    FG4_1  FG4_2    FG5_1    FG6_1 
R4  0.912  −0.353  R26  0.897  R28  0.300  R24  0.894  −0.243  R2  0.994  R8  0.964 
R5  0.949  −0.234  R27  0.882  R36  0.467  R25  0.795  −0.359  R3  0.975  R9  0.957 
R6  0.950  −0.205  R19  0.901  R31  0.394  R32  0.576  −0.541  R1  0.960  R10  0.904 
R7  0.918  −0.189  R18  0.912  R34  0.308  R22  0.730  0.161      R14  0.746 
R13  0.706  −0.058  R20  0.911  R38  0.348  R23  0.740  0.399         
R11  0.613  0.764  R17  0.869  R29  0.194  R35  0.398  0.547         
R12  0.665  0.729  R16  0.908  R15  0.997  R37  0.307  0.599         
      R21  0.859  R30  0.755               
          R33  0.607               
          R39  0.337               
Component scores standardized functions (regression method)
FG1
FG1_1  FG1_1i=0.190·R4i+0.198·R5i+0.198·R6i+0.192·R7i+0.147·R13i+0.128·R11i+0.139·R12i 
FG1_2  FG1_2i=−0.256·R4i0.170·R5i0.149·R6i0.137·R7i0.042·R13i+0.555·R11i+0.530·R12i 
FG2  FG2i=0.141·R26i+0.138·R27i+0.141·R19i+0.143·R18i+0.143·R20i+0.136·R17i+0.142·R16i+0.135·R21i 
FG3  FG3i=0.002·R28i+0.044·R36i+0.006·R31i+0.003·R34i+0.001·R38i+0.001·R29i+0.886·R15i+0.077·R30i+0.040·R33i+0.029·R39i 
FG4
FG4_1  FG4_1i=0.289·R24i+0.257·R25i+0.186·R32i+0.236·R22i+0.239·R23i+0.129·R35i+0.099·R37i 
FG4_2  FG4_2i=−0.184·R24i0.271·R25i0.408·R32i+0.122·R22i+0.301·R23i+0.413·R35i +0.453·R37i 
FG5  FG5i=0.475·R2i+0.275·R3i+0.271·R1i 
FG6  FG6i=0.300·R8i+0.297·R9i+0.281·R10i+0.232·R14i 

Once we identified and obtained the values of the financial dimensions and subdimensions that comprise the financial condition using the regression method, we analyzed the extent of differences based on political factors through an analysis of variance/covariance, controlling the influence of socioeconomic aspects.

We found that the normality of the residuals and the homogeneity of variances were met and the test of between-subjects effects indicates that political factors have statistically significant effects only on the volume of debt (FG1_1), on the degree of financial dependence on transfers from other institutions to perform certain services, particularly for real investments and housing and planning policies (FG4_1), and on balanced budget (FG6_1) (Table 5).

Table 5.

Tests of between-subjects effects.

Source  Dependent variable
  FG1_1  FG1_2  FG2_1  FG3_1  FG4_1  FG4_2  FG5_1  FG6_1 
  P-value
Corrected model  0.001**  0.952  0.000**  0.000**  0.000**  0.000**  0.078  0.003** 
Intercept  0.049*  0.093  0.918  0.234  0.000**  0.113  0.452  0.433 
(PV1) Ideology  0.023*  0.782  0.542  0.384  0.453  0.476  0.026*  0.942 
(PV2) Territoriality of political parties  0.441  0.909  0.826  0.098  0.004**  0.156  0.513  0.641 
(PV3) Government weakness  0.11  0.999  0.831  0.252  0.029*  0.675  0.109  0.018* 
(PV4_1) Provincial partisan alignment  0.274  0.879  0.337  0.233  0.378  0.163  0.147  0.203 
PV4_2) Regional partisan alignment  0.096  0.328  0.781  0.172  0.273  0.804  0.15  0.574 
(PV1) Ideology * (PV2) territoriality of political parties  0.488  0.651  0.447  0.333  0.429  0.465  0.985  0.994 
(PV1) Ideology * (PV3) government weakness  0.384  0.873  0.341  0.735  0.253  0.762  0.513  0.707 
(PV1) Ideology * (PV4_1) provincial partisan alignment  0.976  0.454  0.229  0.008**  0.535  0.005**  0.268  0.185 
(PV1) Ideology * (PV4_2) regional partisan alignment  0.428  0.628  0.609  0.000**  0.003**  0.004**  0.178  0.104 
(SV1) Population  0.176  0.223  0.041*  0.000**  0.000**  0.815  0.627  0.175 
(SV2) Immigrants  0.003**  0.173  0.000**  0.000**  0.104  0.006**  0.391  0.009** 
(SV3) Population change (2004–2009)  0.304  0.836  0.001**  0.634  0.000**  0.006**  0.912  0.181 
(SV4) Immigrants change (2004–2009)  0.476  0.440  0.003**  0.349  0.066  0.003**  0.605  0.292 
(SV5) Density  0.002**  0.977  0.003**  0.024*  0.084  0.625  0.844  0.217 
(SV6) Unemployment index  0.024*  0.232  0.002**  0.000**  0.000**  0.184  0.104  0.214 
(SV7) Unemployment evolution  0.773  0.584  0.095  0.383  0.028*  0.013*  0.647  0.966 
(SV8) Economic activity index  0.484  0.354  0.008**  0.000**  0.001**  0.673  0.636  0.136 
(SV9) Economic activity evolution  0.61  0.834  0.652  0.393  0.495  0.576  0.914  0.418 
*

Significant at 0.05.

**

Significant at 0.01.

Ideology. The model reflects a significant influence of the ideology factor (PV1) on the volume of debt of the entity (FG1_1) and on the dimension of cash solvency (FG5_1) (Table 5). Specifically, the municipalities governed by political parties that have no ideology clearly positioned (not defined) as progressive or conservative have a level of debt (FG1_1) significantly lower than that of the entities that are governed by progressive parties or conservative parties (see Table 6). The mean differences between progressives and conservatives parties are not significant. The mean differences in relation to the cash solvency dimension (FG5_1) (Table 6) also show that the entities governed by the parties without an ideological option defined have higher standards of cash solvency than municipalities managed by progressive parties or by conservative parties.

Table 6.

Pairwise comparisons. Dependent variables FG1_1 and FG5_1.

(I) (PV1) Ideology (1, 2, 3)  (J) (PV1) Ideology (1, 2, 3)  Mean difference (I−J)  Std. error  Sig.  95% confidence interval for difference
          Lower bound  Upper bound 
Dependent variable: FG1_1
(1)Progressive(2) Conservative  −0.588a  0.380  0.122  −1.335  0.159 
(3) Not defined  0.663a,*,b  0.259  0.011  0.153  1.173 
(2)Conservative(1) Progressive  0.588b  0.380  0.122  −0.159  1.335 
(3) Not defined  1.251**,b  0.402  0.002  0.461  2.042 
(3)Not defined(1) Progressive  −0.663a,*,b  0.259  0.011  −1.173  −0.153 
(2) Conservative  −1.251a,**  0.402  0.002  −2.042  −0.461 
Dependent variable:FG5_1
(1)Progressive(2) Conservative  0.588a  0.387  0.130  −0.174  1.350 
(3) Not defined  −0.736a,*,b  0.265  0.006  −1.256  −0.215 
(2)Conservative(1) Progressive  −0.588b  0.387  0.130  −1.350  0.174 
(3) Not defined  −1.323*,b  0.410  0.001  −2.130  −0.517 
(3)Not defined(1) Progressive  0.736a,*,b  0.265  0.006  0.215  1.256 
(2) Conservative  1.323a,*  0.410  0.001  0.517  2.130 

Based on estimated marginal means.

**

Significant at 0.01.

*

Significant at 0.05.

a

An estimate of the modified population marginal mean (I).

b

An estimate of the modified population marginal mean (J).

Territoriality of political parties. The territorial nature of political parties (PV2) only has a statistically significant influence on the variable (FG4_1) dependence on transfers (Table 5). Therefore, PV2 is only influencing the ratio between transfers received and transfers made, the real investments, housing and urban policies and, to a lesser extent, the implementation of policies of social protection and economic policies. Specifically, municipalities governed by regional political parties have a higher level of dependence on transfers than those governed by national parties (Table 7).

Table 7.

Pairwise comparisons. Dependent variable FG4_1.

(I) (PV2) Territorial nature of the political party  (J) (PV2) Territorial nature of the political party  Mean difference (I−J)  Std. error  Sig.  95% confidence interval for difference
          Lower bound  Upper bound 
(1)National(2) Regional  −0.569a  0.177  0.001  −0.918  −0.220 
(3) Local  −0.162a,b  0.493  0.742  −1.132  0.808 
(2)Regional(1) National  0.569b  0.177  0.001  0.220  0.918 
(3) Local  0.407b  0.541  0.452  −0.656  1.470 
(3)Local(1) National  0.162a,b  0.493  0.742  −0.808  1.132 
(2) Regional  −0.407a  0.541  0.452  −1.470  0.656 

Based on estimated marginal means.

a

An estimate of the modified population marginal mean (I).

b

An estimate of the modified population marginal mean (J).

Government's weakness. The government's weakness (PV3) significantly influences the dimensions FG4_1 and FG6_1 (Table 5). The mean differences (Table 8) indicate that municipalities governed by parties that have an absolute showed a different behavior in relation to fund transfers received and transfers made, real investments, housing and urban development policies (FG4_1). The results seem to move in the opposite direction to the conclusions of Bruce et al. (2007). They note that infrastructure investments are higher when governments lack unity.

Table 8.

Pairwise comparisons. Dependent variables FG4_1 and FG6_1.

(I) (PV3) Government weakness  (J) (PV3) Government weakness  Mean difference (I−J)  Std. error  Sig.  95% confidence interval for difference
          Lower bound  Upper bound 
Dependent variable: FG4_1
(0) Party without absolute majority  (1) Party with absolute majority  −0.318a,b  0.143  0.027  −0.599  −0.037 
(1) Party with absolute majority  (0) Party without absolute majority  0.318a,b  0.143  0.027  0.037  0.599 
Dependent variable: FG6_1
(0) Party without absolute majority  (1) Party with absolute majority  −0.389a,b  0.162  0.017  −0.707  −0.070 
(1) Party with absolute majority  (0) Party without absolute majority  0.389a,b  0.162  0.017  0.070  0.707 

Based on estimated marginal means.

a

An estimate of the modified population marginal mean (I).

b

An estimate of the modified population marginal mean (J).

In addition, if the ruling parties have an absolute majority, they improve the balance in budgets (FG6_1) (Table 8).

Partisan alignment. We could not find significant evidence to support the partisan alignment of the municipal governments (PV4_1 and PV4_2).

4Conclusions

Many works in the literature have studied the effects of various political situations on public financial management. They have focused on the analysis of specific financial issues such as debt, deficits, transfers, expenses, income, or taxes, using as independent variables specific political factors, such as ideology, government weakness, political cycles, and partisan alignment. In contrast to these previous works, we have used a global concept of the financial health of public institutions, that is, the financial condition, and on this basis, we analyzed the incidence of multiple political factors.

Using a multivariate approach and a very large set of financial indicators (39) on almost all Spanish municipalities with population on over 20,000, we have identified 8 different financial dimensions or sub-dimensions within the overall concept of financial condition.

As the aim of our study was to understand the possible relationship between the essence of the policy options and all aspects of the financial condition of Spanish municipalities, we selected the most distant year of elections in order to eliminate possible effects of the electoral process.

We found that those parties that have no clear ideological position show a debt management and a short-term solvency better than parties identified ideologically as progressives or conservatives. In our study, we could not find that the municipalities governed by progressive or conservative parties differ in their financial health. Similar results were obtained by Alesina and Tabellini (1990), and Franzese (2002), and opposite results were obtained by Persson and Svensson (1989).

Our analysis of financial condition allowed us to identify a financial behavior about ratio between transfers received and transfers made, the real investments, housing and urban policies and, to a lesser extent, the implementation of policies of social protection and economic policies. This behavior is clearly influenced by the territoriality of political parties, which confirms the theory of Hearl et al. (1996) and Brancati (2008), and the government's weakness, which seems to move in the opposite direction to the conclusions of Bruce et al. (2007). They note that infrastructure investments are higher when governments lack unity, and this conclusion was confirmed by Goeminne et al. (2008) in the Flemish municipalities.

Moreover, our study confirms the government weak hypothesis in Spanish municipalities, because the municipalities in which there is no political party with an absolute majority present major fiscal imbalances (Alesina & Perotti, 1995; Roubini & Sachs, 1989). In addition, we could not verify the influence of the partisan alignment on any financial dimension, which contrasts notably with those noted by Solé-Ollé and Sorribas-Navarro (2008) and Curto-Grau et al. (2012).

References
[Alesina and Perotti, 1995]
A. Alesina, R. Perotti.
The political economy of budget deficits.
IMF Staffs Papers, 42 (1995), pp. 1-31
[Alesina and Tabellini, 1990]
A. Alesina, G. Tabellini.
A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt.
Review of Economic Studies, 57 (1990), pp. 403-414
[Ashworth et al., 2005]
J. Ashworth, B. Geys, B. Heyndels.
Government weakness and local public debt development in Flemish municipalities.
International Tax and Public Finance, 12 (2005), pp. 395-422
[Benito and Bastida, 2010]
B. Benito, F.J. Bastida.
Politics and financial management: A long-term evaluation on Spanish local governments.
International Journal of Critical Accounting, 2 (2010), pp. 249-266
[Berne, 1992]
R. Berne.
The Relationships between Financial Reporting and the Measurement of Financial Condition.
GASB, (1992),
[Borge, 2005]
L.E. Borge.
Strong politicians, small deficits: Evidence from Norwegian local governments.
European Journal of Political Economy, 21 (2005), pp. 325-344
[Bosch and Suarez-Pandiello, 1995]
N. Bosch, J. Suarez-Pandiello.
Seven hypotheses about public choice and local spending: A test for Spanish municipalities.
Public Finance, 50 (1995), pp. 36-50
[Brancati, 2008]
D. Brancati.
The origins and strengths of regional parties.
British Journal of Political Science, 38 (2008), pp. 135-159
[Brollo and Nannicini, 2010]
F. Brollo, T. Nannicini.
Tying your enemy's hands in close races: The politics of federal transfers in Brazil.
IZA Discussion Papers 5698, (2010),
[Bruce et al., 2007]
D. Bruce, D.A. Carrol, J.A. Deskins, J.C. Rork.
Road to ruin? A spatial analysis of state highway spending.
Public Budgeting & Finance, 27 (2007), pp. 66-85
[Cabaleiro et al., 2012]
R. Cabaleiro, E. Buch, A. Vaamonde.
Developing a method to assessing the municipal financial health.
American Review of Public Administration, (2012),
[CICA, 1997]
Canadian Institute of Chartered Accountants (CICA).
Indicators of government financial condition.
CICA, (1997),
[CICA, 2009]
Canadian Institute of Chartered Accountants (CICA).
Public Sector Statements of Recommended Practice (SORP) 4. Indicators of financial condition.
CICA, (2009),
[Carmeli, 2003]
A. Carmeli.
Introduction: Fiscal and financial crises of local governments.
International Journal of Public Administration, 26 (2003), pp. 1423-1430
[Carmeli and Cohen, 2001]
A. Carmeli, A. Cohen.
The financial crisis of the local authorities in Israel: A resource-based analysis.
Public Administration, 79 (2001), pp. 893-913
[Clark, 1977]
T.N. Clark.
Fiscal management of American cities: Funds flow indicators.
Journal of Accounting Research, 15 (1977), pp. 54-94
[Clark, 1994]
T.N. Clark.
Municipal fiscal strain: Indicators and causes.
Government Finance Review, 10 (1994), pp. 27-29
[Curto-Grau et al., 2012]
M. Curto-Grau, A. Solé-Ollé, P. Sorribas-Navarro.
The returns to partisan alignment between layers of government.
CESifo Area Conference on Public Sector Economics,
[Desposato, 2004]
S. Desposato.
The impact of federalism on national political parties in Brazil.
Legislative Studies Quarterly, 29 (2004), pp. 259-285
[Diaz-Cayeros et al., 2006]
A. Diaz-Cayeros, B. Magaloni, B. Weingast.
Tragic brilliance: Equilibrium party hegemony in Mexico.
Working Paper, Hoover Institution, (2006),
[Franzese, 2002]
R.J. Franzese.
Electoral and partisan cycles in economic policies and outcomes.
Annual Review of Political Science, 5 (2002), pp. 369-421
[García-Sánchez et al., 2012]
I.M. García-Sánchez, N. Mordan, J.M. Prado-Lorenzo.
Effect of the political system on local financial condition: Empirical evidence for Spain's largest municipalities.
Public Budgeting & Finance, 32 (2012), pp. 40-68
[Geys, 2007]
B. Geys.
Government weakness and local public debt cycles: Evidence from Flemish municipalities.
Local Government Studies, 33 (2007), pp. 239-253
[Goeminne et al., 2008]
S. Goeminne, B. Geys, C. Smolders.
Political fragmentation and projected tax revenues: Evidence from Flemish municipalities.
International Tax and Public Finance, 115 (2008), pp. 297-315
[Groves et al., 1981]
S.M. Groves, W.M. Godsey, M.A. Shulman.
Financial indicators for local governments.
Public Budgeting and Finance, 1 (1981), pp. 5-19
[Hearl et al., 1996]
D. Hearl, J.I. Budge, B. Pearson.
Distinctiveness of regional voting: A comparative analysis across the European community countries (1979–93).
Electoral Studies, 15 (1996), pp. 167-182
[Hendrick, 2004]
R. Hendrick.
Assessing and measuring the fiscal heath of local governments.
Urban Affairs Review, 40 (2004), pp. 78-114
[Honadle, 2003]
B.W. Honadle.
The states’ role in U.S. local government fiscal crises: A theoretical model and results of a national survey.
International Journal of Public Administration, 26 (2003), pp. 1431-1472
[Honadle et al., 2004]
B.W. Honadle, J.M. Costa, B.A. Cigler.
Fiscal heath for local governments.
Elsevier Academic Press, (2004),
[ICMA, 2003]
International City/County Management Association [ICMA].
Evaluating financial condition. A handbook for local government.
4th ed., ICMA, (2003),
[Kloha et al., 2005]
P. Kloha, C.S. Weissert, R. Kleine.
Someone to watch over me: State monitoring of local fiscal conditions.
The American Review of Public Administration, 35 (2005), pp. 236-255
[Mercer and Gilbert, 1996]
T. Mercer, M. Gilbert.
A financial condition index for Nova Scotia municipalities.
Government Finance Review, 12 (1996), pp. 36-38
[Persson and Svensson, 1989]
T. Persson, L. Svensson.
Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: Policy with time-inconsistent preferences.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104 (1989), pp. 325-345
[Poterba, 1994]
J.M. Poterba.
State responses to fiscal crises – The effects of budgetary institutions and politics.
Journal of Political Economy, 102 (1994), pp. 799-821
[Rattsø and Tovmo, 2002]
J. Rattsø, P. Tovmo.
Fiscal discipline and asymmetric adjustment of revenues and expenditures: Local government responses to shocks in Denmark.
Public Finance Review, 30 (2002), pp. 208-234
[Rivenbark and Roenigk, 2011]
W.C. Rivenbark, D.J. Roenigk.
Implementation of financial condition analysis in local governments.
Public Administration Quarterly, 35 (2011), pp. 238-264
[Roubini and Sachs, 1989]
N. Roubini, J.D. Sachs.
Political and economic determinants of Budget deficits in the industrial democracies.
European Economic Review, 33 (1989), pp. 903-938
[Scheiner, 2005]
E. Scheiner.
Pipelines of pork. Japanese politics and a model of local opposition party failure.
Comparative Political Studies, 38 (2005), pp. 799-823
[Sohl et al., 2009]
S. Sohl, M.T. Peddle, K. Thurmaier, C.H. Wood, G. Kuhn.
Measuring the financial position of municipalities: Numbers do not speak for themselves.
Public Budgeting & Finance, (2009), pp. 74-96
[Solé-Ollé and Sorribas-Navarro, 2008]
A. Solé-Ollé, P. Sorribas-Navarro.
The effects of partisan alignment on the allocation of intergovernmental transfers. Differences-in-differences estimates for Spain.
Journal of Public Economics, 92 (2008), pp. 2302-2319
[Stokes, 2005]
S.C. Stokes.
Perverse accountability: A formal model of machine politics with evidence from Argentina.
American Political Science Review, 99 (2005), pp. 315-325
[Tuffe, 1978]
E. Tuffe.
Political control of the economy.
Princeton University Press, (1978),
[Veiga and Veiga, 2007]
L.G. Veiga, F.J. Veiga.
Political business cycles at the municipal level.
Public Choice, 131 (2007), pp. 45-64
[Wang et al., 2007]
X. Wang, L. Dennis, Y.S. Tu.
Measuring financial condition: A study of U.S. states.
Public Budgeting and Finance, 27 (2007), pp. 1-21
[Wildavsky, 1967]
A.B. Wildavsky.
Party discipline under federalism: Implication of the Australian experience.
American federalism in perspective, pp. 162-181
Copyright © 2013. AEDEM
Opciones de artículo
es en pt

¿Es usted profesional sanitario apto para prescribir o dispensar medicamentos?

Are you a health professional able to prescribe or dispense drugs?

Você é um profissional de saúde habilitado a prescrever ou dispensar medicamentos