covid
Buscar en
BRQ Business Research Quarterly
Toda la web
Inicio BRQ Business Research Quarterly Investment decisions of companies in financial distress
Journal Information
Vol. 18. Issue 3.
Pages 174-187 (July - September 2015)
Share
Share
Download PDF
More article options
Visits
4109
Vol. 18. Issue 3.
Pages 174-187 (July - September 2015)
Article
Open Access
Investment decisions of companies in financial distress
Visits
4109
Carlos López-Gutiérrez
Corresponding author
carlos.lopez@unican.es

Corresponding author. Tel.: +34 942203906; fax: +34 942201890.
, Sergio Sanfilippo-Azofra, Begoña Torre-Olmo
University of Cantabria, Business Administration Faculty, Avd. Los Castros S/N, Santander 39005, Cantabria, Spain
This item has received

Under a Creative Commons license
Article information
Abstract
Full Text
Bibliography
Download PDF
Statistics
Tables (7)
Table 1. Temporal and country distribution.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics I.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics II.
Table 4. Descriptive statistics III.
Table 5. Results of panel data analysis.
Table 6. Robustness test (sample divided according to Tobin's q).
Table 7. Robustness test (sample divided according to the over and under investment intensity).
Show moreShow less
Abstract

This paper analyzes the influence of financial distress on the investment behavior of companies. The analysis includes companies from Germany, Canada, Spain, France, Italy, UK and USA, which cover a wide spectrum of different institutional environments. The methodology used is panel data estimation using the Generalized Method of Moments (System-GMM), thereby allowing control of both unobservable heterogeneity and the problems of endogeneity in explanatory variables. The results show that the influence of financial distress on investment is different according to the investment opportunities available to companies. So, companies in difficulties with fewer opportunities have the greatest propensity to under-invest, while firms in difficulties with better opportunities do not present different investment behavior than healthy companies.

Keywords:
Financial distress
Over-investment
Under-investment
Tobin's q
JEL classification:
G33
G32
Full Text
Introduction

Financial literature widely discusses the investment decisions of companies. The study of the relationship between cash flow and investment level is the most common way of analyzing the problems of over- and under-investment (Kaplan and Zingales, 1997; Cleary, 1999; Fazzari et al., 1988; Hoshi et al., 1991). However, the study of over- and under-investment decisions in companies in financial distress is a topic that still requires more in-depth study.

Previous literature on investment decisions identifies the existence of financial constraints as a key variable. Bhagat et al. (2005) found that “financially distressed firms behave differently from financially constrained firms”, so the results considering financial constraints are not directly applicable to companies in financial distress, even considering that companies in financial distress are subject to such constraints. We must take into account that the degree of financial constraint is not observable, so different papers use different proxies that are not related with the financial situation of the firm.1

The influence of financial distress on the investment behavior of firms has been analyzed indirectly in some papers. Whited (1992) studied the behavior investment when firms are subject to borrowing constraints, finding that difficulties in obtaining debt finance have an impact on investment. Bhagat et al. (2005) analyzed the investment–cash flow sensitivity of firms in financial distress, finding that the relationship between investment and internal funds for these firms is conditioned by operating profits. White (1996) proposes, from a theoretical point of view, that the problems of over- and under-investment can be exacerbated in companies in financial distress even before they file for bankruptcy. However, previous works have not empirically tested this approach until now, since they do not study the effect that financial distress has on a firm's investment policy.

The main contribution of this work is to conduct an empirical analysis on over and under-investment problems, explicitly considering the implications that the existence of financial distress has on the investment behavior of companies. The paper proposes several hypotheses that relate the existence of financial distress to problems of over- and under-investment. The proposal is that the very existence of difficulties is a crucial factor in explaining the investment behavior of firms. However, not all firms in distress will show similar behavior. Those who have fewer opportunities for investment will have a greater tendency to under invest, while, in the opposite case, problems of over-investment could arise.

The testing of these hypotheses is complex, since it is necessary to have a variable to measure the degree of over- and under-investment by companies. To address this problem, unlike the previous empirical work, this article proposes a measure of the investment behavior of firms that allows determining whether firms in distress have a higher propensity to over- or under-invest. This measure is the level of investment relative to investment opportunities available to the firm (measured by Tobin's q). In addition, the empirical analysis takes into account all firms, healthy and financially distressed, allowing the analysis of whether the investment behavior differs for the two groups of companies.

The analysis includes companies from Germany, Canada, Spain, France, Italy, UK and USA, which cover a wide spectrum of different institutional environments. The methodology used is panel data estimation using the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). This methodology allows controlling both unobservable heterogeneity and the problems of endogeneity in explanatory variables through the use of instruments.

The results show that the influence of financial distress on investment is different in accordance with the investment opportunities available to the company. Therefore, the companies with fewer opportunities have the greatest propensity to under-invest, while firms in difficulties with greater opportunities do not present different investment behavior than healthy companies.

Theory and testable hypotheses

The introduction of imperfections in capital markets in the model of Modigliani and Miller (1958) means that companies will not always be able to make all the investments that create value. In these situations, the company may encounter problems from sub-optimal investment decisions due to the existence of imperfections in capital markets, such as information asymmetry and agency costs. In other words, it may occur that the firms do not undertake all profitable projects, under-investment, or that the firm carry out excessively risky projects with a negative net present value, over-investment (Morgado and Pindado (2003) present a comprehensive review of these problems).

Financial literature contains numerous studies that examine investment decisions and all the problems associated with such decisions in companies. Most of these studies focus on analyzing the sensitivity of the investment decision to the availability of cash flow. However, several factors affect this relationship between investment and cash flow. According to Hoshi et al. (1991), a problem in analyzing this relationship is that the generation of greater cash flow may be a sign of good management in the past and such companies are more likely to remain well managed in the future. In this case, these companies have more liquidity and would have greater investment opportunities, which would lead to a higher level of investment due to the higher level of management and not only the availability of higher cash flow.

Existing literature focuses on studying these different interpretations of the relationship between investment and cash flow. In order to go deeper into the analysis of the relationship between internal funds and investment, researchers have taken into account the existence of growth opportunities and financial constraints. The results show a positive relationship between growth opportunities and the level of investment, but with regard to financial constraints, the results are less clear. On the one hand, some authors find that companies with higher financial constraints have a greater sensitivity to cash flow (Lopez Iturriaga, 2006; Hoshi et al., 1991; Fazzari et al., 2000). On the other hand, other studies find the opposite relationship, that is, greater sensitivity to cash flow for companies with fewer restrictions (Kaplan and Zingales, 1997, 2000; Cleary, 1999; Kadapakkam et al., 1998).2

However, all these studies exclude companies in financial distress from the analysis because their own financial situation will condition their investment behavior. One of the defining characteristics of firms in distress is the existence of financial constraints and strained access to credit, stemming from their situation. However, Bhagat et al. (2005) find that firms in financial distress do not behave the same way as companies with financial constraints. In a descriptive analysis of their sample, they find that financially distressed firms have some characteristics in common with most financially constrained firms, such as a greater Tobin's q, a smaller size or a higher market-to-book ratio. However, they find that, in contrast to most financially constrained firms, companies in financial distress invest less, have lower free cash flows, higher leverage and lower growth rate of sales. Due to these differences, Bhagat et al. (2005) conclude that the investment behavior of firms in distress in response to variations in cash flow differs from that of the rest of the companies with financial constraints.

In the same way, Pindado et al. (2008) also find evidence of differential investment behavior presented by firms in distress. Their results show that the characteristics of insolvency laws exert a distorting effect on investment decisions of firms given that they play a fundamental role in explaining the sensitivity of investments to cash flow. According to their results, the higher the ex-ante bankruptcy costs, the lower the level of investment.

However, these studies focus their attention on the effect that cash flow has on the level of investment, but do not take into account other different behavior of companies with insolvency problems. There are different factors that can explain the different behavior of companies in financial distress. Firstly, what is called the “punishment” effect for managers, which encourages them to make decisions with the purpose of preventing the firm from having insolvency problems. The situation in which managers find themselves when their firm is having financial problems exercises its influence on the manager's level of effort (White, 1996), affecting their motivations for choosing the investment projects.

Secondly, bankruptcy laws can affect the financing of the company, which can affect its investment capacity. On the one hand, Davydenko and Franks (2008) and Qian and Strahan (2007) find that the characteristics of bankruptcy laws are a determining factor of financial institutions’ behavior upon financing each country's firms (it affects recovery rates, the maturity of transactions and the collateral required). On the other hand, the orientation of the bankruptcy laws (debtor or creditor oriented) may lead to suboptimal investment decisions (López Gutiérrez et al., 2012). These investment problems may be behind the low recovery capacity that the different restructuring procedures presented (Couwenberg, 2001), as well as the loss of value of companies in distress (López Gutiérrez et al., 2009).

Considering all these factors, from a theoretical point of view, the very fact that companies are in financial distress can exacerbate the problems of over- and under-investment. The problems of under-investment get worse because shareholders and managers have no incentive to make profitable investments, unless in doing so, they can significantly reduce the probability of bankruptcy. This is because such projects reduce the variability of the company's returns, only improving the situation of creditors (White, 1996). The problems of over-investment may also increase in companies in financial distress, with managers having strong incentives to undertake excessively risky investments. If the project is successful, it avoids or at least delays the entry into bankruptcy proceedings, while, if the project fails, the creditors bear the cost.

To sum up, the study focuses on the influence of financial distress on the investment policy of the company, taking into account the investment opportunities, which could condition the investment behavior of firms in distress. On the one hand, in the case of firms with fewer investment opportunities, if the managers expect that the performance of those investments is not enough to avoid bankruptcy, they have strong incentives to reject projects even with a positive net present value. This leads to the first hypothesis:H1a

Firms with fewer investment opportunities present greater propensity to under-invest.

On the other hand, if there are more investment opportunities that, if successful, would allow the firm to avoid bankruptcy, managers could make very risky investments, even with negative net present values, since they benefit from the success while the creditors bear the cost of any failure. Accordingly, the second hypothesis isH1b

Firms in distress with greater investment opportunities present greater propensity to over-invest.

Sample

The sample includes firms from Germany, Canada, Spain, France, Italy, the United Kingdom and the United States. The inclusion of these countries allows covering companies operating under different institutional environments with a broad spectrum of bankruptcy systems. This prevents that these circumstances condition the analysis by controlling for the country.

The sample consists of non-financial listed firms between 1996 and 2006. We restrict the sample period to end in 2006 so that our results are not affected by the financial crisis. After the onset of the financial crisis, the firms’ financing behavior could be conditioned more by the availability of funds in the economy and the disruption of the financial systems than by the firms’ situation, which could have given rise to a bias in our results.

Each country presents an unbalanced panel made up of companies with available data for at least 5 consecutive years. This condition is necessary to test the second order serial correlation (Arellano and Bond, 1991), which is fundamental for guaranteeing the robustness of the estimations using the System GMM methodology.

The sample consists of a total of 4029 companies and 31,010 observations. Table 1 contains the temporal and country distribution of the number of firms of the sample.

Table 1.

Temporal and country distribution.

Year  Canada  France  Germany  Italy  Spain  UK  USA  Total 
1996  81  131  191  56  42  349  981  1831 
1997  98  141  198  60  45  370  1141  2053 
1998  110  149  205  67  52  393  1270  2246 
1999  118  156  223  73  54  474  1450  2548 
2000  167  147  218  78  55  510  1670  2845 
2001  190  245  267  118  61  538  1718  3137 
2002  224  270  288  133  67  600  1825  3407 
2003  255  293  316  154  73  630  1808  3529 
2004  244  288  309  153  72  613  1699  3378 
2005  237  260  302  145  69  591  1600  3204 
2006  213  217  276  135  66  545  1380  2832 
Number of firms (n279  332  378  159  77  676  2128  4029 
Total observations (N1937  2297  2793  1172  656  5613  16,542  31,010 

By including only listed companies, the number of firms traded on each of the securities exchanges conditions the size by country. However, the table shows that the sample size, for all years and countries analyzed, is adequate for performing the analysis. The information needed to carry out the analysis comes from the Datastream database of the Thomson Financial Services Group.

Empirical method

To test for the influence of the existence of financial distress on the investment behavior of companies, the model we propose follows this specification:

Model 1:

As dependent variable, the study proposes the use of a relative variable to allow the analysis of the effect produced on under-investment or over-investment. Traditionally, studies use the ratio of investment to replacement value of the firm's assets (I/K), but this does not directly reflect whether the company is over- or under-investing according to the available investment opportunities. To overcome this limitation, the study proposes the use of the classical measures of the level of investment and divides it by the investment opportunities as measured by Tobin's q. This variable has a series of advantages over others commonly used in literature, since it allows the analysis of the level of investment relative to the investment opportunities that the company has. A positive and significant coefficient associated with one of the independent variables implies that this variable promotes the existence of over-investment, while a negative coefficient reflects a greater propensity toward under-investment.

To introduce the financial distress situation in the model, we define a dummy variable (DIF) that takes value 1 when the company is in financial distress and zero otherwise. A negative coefficient associated to this variable implies that the firms in financial difficulties have less propensity to invest than healthy firms, taking into account their investment opportunities. To identify firms in financial distress the study uses three alternative measures, since this situation is not directly observable. Thus, the results are more robust as regards the identification of firms in distress (see Appendix). The first measure is the Z″-Score model of Altman (2002). This measure is a modification of the original Z-Score model (Altman, 1968), which was developed in order to minimize the potential industry effect and is used to assess the financial health of non-U.S. corporates. According to Altman (2002), the value of Z″-score has the following intervals. Values higher than 2.6 are considered the “safe zone”, and means that the possibility of bankruptcy is very low. Values between 1.1 and 2.6 are considered the “gray zone” or “zone of ignorance”, because of the susceptibility to error classification. Values below 1.10 are considered “distress zone”, and it means that the possibility of bankruptcy is high. So, we identify firms in financial distress when they are situated in the “distress zone”, when they have a Z″-score less than 1.10 (DIF1). Secondly, firms in financial distress include those that, in a given year, have a lower EBITDA than financial expenses (DIF2) (Bhagat et al., 2005; Wruck, 1990; Asquith et al., 1994; Andrade and Kaplan, 1998; Pindado et al., 2008; Whitaker, 1999). The last measure is the model of Ohlson (1980), considering a firm to be in financial distress in a given year when it has a probability of default greater or equal to 50% (DIF3).

In addition, the investment opportunities that exist can condition the investment behavior of firms in financial distress. To include this constraint in the analysis, the model includes a dummy variable (QD) that takes the value 1 if Tobin's q is greater than 1 and zero otherwise. This variable (QD) allows us to identify companies that have greater investment opportunities, where Tobin's q is greater than 1, and those companies with fewer opportunities available, which have a Tobin's q of less than 1.3 This dummy variable QD is introduced into the model interacting with the financial distress variable (DIFit).

For companies in financial distress and fewer investment opportunities, a test of the null hypothesis H0: β4=0 is necessary. If this null hypothesis is rejected, the coefficient β4 is statistically different from zero and measures the sensitivity of the propensity to invest to the existence of financial distress for companies with few investment opportunities. The introduction of the interaction variable into the model allows us to test the situation for firms that have greater investment opportunities. In order to interpret the interaction variables correctly, it is necessary to perform a linear restriction test to verify the significance of the sums of the coefficients. The null hypothesis is H0: β4+β5=0. Rejecting this null hypothesis, the coefficient (β4+β5) is statistically different from zero and measures the sensitivity of the propensity to invest to the existence of financial distress for companies with greater investment opportunities.

To investigate the relationship between investment and financial distress, we control for variables that affect the firms’ investment behavior. We included some widely considered factors in the previous literature: the internal funds generated for each firm (CF) (Fazzari et al., 1988, 2000; Hoshi et al., 1991; Lang et al., 1996); the firm's size (SIZE) (Kadapakkam et al., 1998); the firm's leverage (LEV) (Lang et al., 1996); and the firm's industry (SECTOR) (Hoshi et al., 1991). Lastly, country and year effect dummies are included to capture country and year-specific factors.

The definition of the variables is presented in the Appendix.

The model is estimated using panel data methodology. This allows controlling for unobservable heterogeneity. The differences that exist between the companies gives rise to characteristics that influence their propensity to invest that are not easily observable or measurable and therefore cannot be introduced into a model. The use of panel data allows controlling for this heterogeneity by taking the first differences and thereby eliminating the individual effect, which allows avoiding any bias in the results. In particular, the models are estimated using two steps System-GMM (Generalized Method of Moments) with robust errors, which is consistent in the presence of any pattern of heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation (Arellano and Bover, 1995; Blundell and Bond, 1998). This estimator allows controlling for problems of endogeneity by using instruments. In particular, the model includes the lagged explanatory variables as instruments, which allows for additional instruments by taking advantage of the conditions of orthogonality existing between the lags in the independent variables of the model (Arellano and Bond, 1991). The CF, SIZE and LEV variables are considered endogenous because these variables could be affected by the investment decisions. The financial distress variable is considered exogenous because investment has not been included as an explanatory variable of financial distress in the literature (Mossman et al., 1998; Altman and Hotchkiss, 2006). For the endogenous variables, first or deeper lags have been used as instruments. The exogenous variable is instrumented by itself.

Empirical evidence

This section describes basic characteristics of the data, discusses the results of our empirical analyses in some detail, and presents some robustness tests.

Data description

Outlier identification is important in many applications of multivariate analysis in order to preserve the results from possible harmful effects (Santos-Pereira and Pires, 2002). To ensure that the results are not driven by outliers, we remove observations with extreme values for our control variables. This allows avoiding bias in our results. So, we applied the following filters: (1) we remove firms with Tobin's q over 20; (2) we remove firms with I greater than 2 or smaller than −2; (3) we remove firms with CF/K greater than 2 or smaller than −2.

Tables 2–4 provide descriptive statistics for the sample, distinguishing among the firms classified according to the three alternative methods described above. The sample size when using the Ohlson model is smaller due to the lower availability of the data required for the calculation. We also compare the firms with Tobin's q over or under one, in order to test the differences according to this variable. Additionally, we present the Wilcoxon rank-sum test, comparing the mean of the two subsamples in each case.

Table 2.

Descriptive statistics I.

  Total sampleTotal sample Q>1Total sample Q<1   
N  31,01026,2574753   
n  402938801376   
Variable  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig. 
I  0.076  0.123  −1.842  0.918  0.080  0.122  −1.842  0.918  0.051  0.123  −1.438  0.820  −19.69  *** 
Q  2.168  1.785  0.039  19.903  2.412  1.837  1.000  19.903  0.823  0.145  0.039  1.000  −109.88  *** 
Num Q  4770  22,600  0.354  960,000  5499  24,400  0.354  960,000  747  3089  0.512  62,900  −48.85  *** 
K  2208  8825  0.053  252,000  2456  9466  0.053  252,000  836  3303  1.285  65,700  −22.96  *** 
I/Q  0.046  0.098  −5.626  1.551  0.043  0.074  −1.077  0.808  0.062  0.178  −5.626  1.551  18.50  *** 
CF  0.112  0.226  −1.918  1.959  0.122  0.233  −1.918  1.959  0.055  0.174  −1.713  1.105  −43.01  *** 
SIZE  5.479  0.908  1.769  8.754  5.541  0.921  1.769  8.754  5.140  0.746  3.122  7.812  −28.87  *** 
LEV  0.554  0.256  0.003  9.681  0.561  0.264  0.004  9.681  0.513  0.204  0.003  1.477  −10.39  *** 

Z is the Wilcoxon rank-sum test.

***

A level of significance of 0.01.

Table 3.

Descriptive statistics II.

  Distressed firms (DIF1)Healthy firms (DIF1)   
N (n4404 (1470)26,606 (3917)   
Variable  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig. 
I  0.063  0.171  −1.398  0.751  0.078  0.113  −1.842  0.918  7.81  *** 
Q  2.364  2.023  0.305  18.460  2.136  1.741  0.039  19.903  −7.60  *** 
Num Q  7183  42,200  0.354  960,000  4371  17,300  0.512  475,000  10.36  *** 
K  3477  15,000  0.053  252,000  1997  7282  0.814  220,000  12.62  *** 
I/Q  0.032  0.125  −1.332  1.077  0.048  0.093  −5.626  1.551  12.32  *** 
CF  0.043  0.319  −1.918  1.959  0.123  0.205  −1.887  1.903  22.11  *** 
SIZE  5.351  1.095  1.769  8.754  5.501  0.871  2.870  8.432  11.53  *** 
LEV  0.802  0.377  0.016  9.681  0.513  0.203  0.003  2.546  −62.65  *** 
  Distressed firms (DIF2)Healthy firms (DIF2)   
N (n4868 (1770)26,142 (3823)   
Variable  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig. 
I  0.044  0.160  −1.371  0.836  0.082  0.114  −1.842  0.918  27.33  *** 
Q  2.607  2.327  0.039  18.683  2.086  1.652  0.072  19.903  −11.64  *** 
Num Q  880  5254  0.354  147,000  5495  24,400  0.904  960,000  50.18  *** 
K  477  2699  0.053  80,300  2530  9506  0.814  252,000  56.36  *** 
I/Q  0.018  0.147  −5.626  1.451  0.051  0.085  −1.602  1.551  32.70  *** 
CF  −0.141  0.356  −1.918  1.959  0.159  0.152  −1.838  1.903  76.14  *** 
SIZE  4.822  0.771  1.769  8.065  5.602  0.878  2.870  8.754  55.88  *** 
LEV  0.560  0.401  0.003  9.681  0.553  0.219  0.004  3.599  6.81  *** 
  Distressed firms (DIF3)Healthy firms (DIF3)   
N (n2437 (988)23,100 (2845)   
Variable  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig. 
I  0.040  0.163  −1.398  0.742  0.078  0.112  −1.816  0.832  16.54  *** 
Q  2.634  2.443  0.193  18.683  2.066  1.602  0.039  19.875  −8.28  *** 
Num Q  900  4802  1.251  134,000  5827  25,600  0.512  960,000  37.09  *** 
K  484  2806  0.579  72,400  2673  9774  1.207  252,000  41.63  *** 
I/Q  0.016  0.166  −5.626  1.077  0.049  0.086  −1.602  1.551  20.07  *** 
CF  −0.046  0.366  −1.796  1.959  0.141  0.168  −1.824  1.894  33.64  *** 
SIZE  4.860  0.771  2.782  7.965  5.643  0.864  3.122  8.754  41.15  *** 
LEV  0.739  0.469  0.006  9.681  0.539  0.205  0.003  2.392  −26.85  *** 

Z is the Wilcoxon rank-sum test.

***

A level of significance of 0.01.

Table 4.

Descriptive statistics III.

  Distressed firms (DIF1) Q>1Distressed firms (DIF1) Q<1    Healthy firms (DIF1) Q>1Healthy firms (DIF1) Q<1   
N (n3879 (1348)525 (291)    22,378 (3744)4228 (1289)   
Variable  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig. 
I  0.068  0.168  −1.398  0.751  0.021  0.188  −0.992  0.742  −7.67  ***  0.082  0.112  −1.842  0.918  0.055  0.112  −1.438  0.820  −18.64  *** 
Q  2.568  2.073  1.000  18.460  0.858  0.126  0.305  0.999  −37.24  ***  2.384  1.791  1.000  19.903  0.819  0.147  0.039  1.000  −103.29  *** 
Num Q  7986  44,900  0.354  960,000  1249  3792  1.156  30,900  −10.58  ***  5067  18,700  1.677  475,000  685  2985  0.512  62,900  −48.97  *** 
K  3760  15,900  0.053  252,000  1392  4141  1.285  32,300  −2.44  **  2230  7798  0.814  220,000  767  3177  1.897  65,700  −24.41  *** 
I/Q  0.033  0.099  −1.077  0.631  0.021  0.239  −1.332  1.077  −0.32    0.044  0.069  −0.998  0.808  0.067  0.169  −5.626  1.551  19.58  *** 
CF  0.043  0.330  −1.918  1.959  0.047  0.221  −1.602  1.105  −5.13  ***  0.136  0.209  −1.887  1.903  0.056  0.167  −1.713  0.728  −45.41  *** 
SIZE  5.384  1.116  1.769  8.754  5.105  0.883  3.122  7.471  −4.99  ***  5.568  0.880  2.870  8.432  5.144  0.727  3.261  7.812  −29.73  *** 
LEV  0.817  0.391  0.025  9.681  0.687  0.212  0.016  1.477  −8.22  ***  0.517  0.205  0.004  2.546  0.491  0.192  0.003  1.012  −6.70  *** 
  Distressed firms (DIF2) Q>1Distressed firms (DIF2) Q<1    Healthy firms (DIF2) Q>1Healthy firms (DIF2) Q<1   
N  4049 (1553)819 (523)    22,208 (3643)3934 (1200)   
Variable  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig. 
I  0.051  0.156  −1.371  0.836  0.009  0.175  −1.087  0.812  −10.71  ***  0.086  0.114  −1.842  0.918  0.060  0.108  −1.438  0.820  −6.22  *** 
Q  2.976  2.387  1.000  18.683  0.783  0.160  0.039  1.000  −45.20  ***  2.309  1.697  1.000  19.903  0.831  0.140  0.072  1.000  −16.93  *** 
Num Q  979  5703  0.354  147,000  393  1748  0.512  14,600  −16.10  ***  6323  26,400  1.677  960,000  821  3296  0.904  62,900  −100.13  *** 
K  479  2815  0.053  80,300  467  2034  1.387  17,800  1.61    2816  10,200  0.814  252,000  912  3505  1.285  65,700  −47.60  *** 
I/Q  0.021  0.088  −1.077  0.730  0.006  0.300  −5.626  1.451  −0.19    0.047  0.071  −1.049  0.808  0.074  0.138  −1.602  1.551  −25.40  *** 
CF  −0.152  0.367  −1.918  1.959  −0.085  0.288  −1.713  1.105  4.30  ***  0.172  0.153  −1.838  1.903  0.084  0.120  −1.710  1.078  20.81  *** 
SIZE  4.830  0.783  1.769  8.065  4.781  0.706  3.143  7.185  −1.17    5.671  0.884  2.870  8.754  5.214  0.732  3.122  7.812  −49.92  *** 
LEV  0.579  0.424  0.004  9.681  0.468  0.235  0.003  1.477  −6.22  ***  0.558  0.223  0.005  3.599  0.522  0.195  0.004  1.449  −30.95  *** 
  Distressed firms (DIF3) Q>1Distressed firms (DIF3) Q<1    Healthy firms (DIF3) Q>1Healthy firms (DIF3) Q<1   
N  2062 (862)375 (249)    19,497 (2730)3603 (992)   
Variable  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig.  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Mean  Std. Dev.  Min  Max  Z  Sig. 
I  0.046  0.160  −1.398  0.732  0.007  0.178  −1.087  0.742  −5.59  ***  0.083  0.112  −1.816  0.832  0.055  0.112  −1.438  0.820  −17.53  *** 
Q  2.961  2.521  1.000  18.683  0.835  0.144  0.193  0.999  −30.85  ***  2.296  1.642  1.000  19.875  0.820  0.147  0.039  1.000  −95.51  *** 
Num Q  960  5103  2.275  134,000  571  2559  1.251  30,900  −8.08  ***  6745  27,700  1.990  960,000  858  3363  0.512  62,900  −47.63  *** 
K  457  2814  0.579  72,400  633  2763  2.707  32,300  2.25  **  2989  10,500  1.207  252,000  960  3598  1.285  65,700  −26.11  *** 
I/Q  0.020  0.094  −0.929  0.631  −0.007  0.361  −5.626  1.077  0.81    0.045  0.070  −1.077  0.664  0.068  0.144  −1.602  1.551  17.68  *** 
CF  −0.056  0.379  −1.796  1.959  0.007  0.280  −1.694  1.105  1.71  *  0.154  0.171  −1.824  1.894  0.070  0.135  −1.713  0.728  −45.34  *** 
SIZE  4.860  0.775  2.782  7.965  4.860  0.748  3.392  7.471  0.14    5.717  0.868  3.145  8.754  5.241  0.726  3.122  7.812  −31.16  *** 
LEV  0.760  0.497  0.019  9.681  0.626  0.237  0.006  1.263  −4.95  ***  0.545  0.207  0.004  2.392  0.507  0.192  0.003  1.012  −9.13  *** 
*

A level of significance of 0.1.

**

A level of significance of 0.05.

***

A level of significance of 0.01.

Table 2 provides descriptive statistics for the whole sample. All the differences are statistically significant. All variables present higher values for firms with Q over one, except the dependent variable of our model (I/Q) which is higher for firms with Q under one.

Table 3 provides information for all variables distinguishing healthy and financially distressed firms. The results show that financially distressed firms invest less, have a higher Tobin's q, smaller cash flows, a smaller size and higher leverage than healthy firms. These results follow the same pattern as Bhagat et al. (2005). The greater value of Tobin's q for firms in financial distress could affect the behavior of our dependent variable. In fact, regarding the variable I/Q, the results show that distressed firms present a smaller value, so they seem not to be able to take advantage of all the investment opportunities they have, at least not in the same way that healthy firms do. So, greater values of Tobin's q lead to greater denominator values and a tendency to underinvestment, as we detected in the results presented in Table 2.

Lastly, there is a need for in-depth analysis so, in Table 4, we present the differences for firms with q over and under one, for both healthy and distressed firms. In the case of healthy firms, the results are similar to those previously obtained for the whole sample, presented in Table 2 (higher values for all the variables except I/Q for firms with Q over one). However, for financially distressed firms the behavior of the variable I/Q is not the same, since we do not observe statistically significant differences between firms with Tobin's q over and under one.

These results suggest that healthy and distressed firms have different investment behavior, but we need to test these findings with multivariable analysis in order to take into account all the variables that might affect this behavior.

Results

Table 5 shows the results of the analysis proposed in model 1.

Table 5.

Results of panel data analysis.

  (1)  (2)  (3) 
Dependent variable  I/Q  I/Q  I/Q 
CF  0.0501  0.1033*  0.0667** 
  (0.88)  (1.66)  (2.01) 
SIZE  −0.0182  −0.0488  −0.0015 
  (−0.46)  (−0.89)  (−0.04) 
LEV  −0.0473*  −0.0465  −0.0667* 
  (−1.92)  (−0.76)  (−1.87) 
DIF1  −0.2294**     
  (−2.50)     
DIF2    −0.1429**   
    (−2.46)   
DIF3      −0.1356** 
      (−2.00) 
DIF1*QD  0.2181**     
  (2.22)     
DIF2*QD    0.1389**   
    (2.40)   
DIF3*QD      0.1308* 
      (1.74) 
CONSTANT  0.3371  0.3062  0.0991 
  (1.48)  (0.65)  (0.49) 
β4+β5  −0.0113  −0.0039  −0.0048 
  (−0.66)  (−0.23)  (−0.37) 
SECTOR  5.23***  1.33  0.63 
COUNTRY  0.42  0.65  0.63 
YEAR  8.29***  1.64*  53.62*** 
m1  −4.42***  −3.85***  −4.54*** 
  [0.000]  [0.000]  [0.000] 
m2  −0.28  0.17  −0.93 
  [0.782]  [0.863]  [0.353] 
Hansen  19.57  7.25  36.41 
  [0.240]  [0.993]  [0.309] 

β4+β5: is the t-statistic for the linear restriction test under the following null hypothesis: H0: β4+β5=0.

SECTOR: Wald's test of the joint significance of the sector's dummy variables. COUNTRY: Wald's test of the joint significance of the country's dummy variables. YEAR: Wald's test of the joint significance of the year's dummy variables. Distributed as a chi-square under the null hypothesis of lack of relationship.

m1 and m2 are the 1st and 2nd order serial correlation statistics using residuals in first differences, distributed as N(0,1) under the null hypothesis of non-serial correlation.

Hansen: over-identifying restriction test, distributed as a chi-square under the null hypothesis of no relation between the instruments and the error term.

t-Statistic between brackets and p-values between square brackets.

*

A level of significance of 0.1.

**

A level of significance of 0.05.

***

A level of significance of 0.01.

According to Hypothesis 1a, coefficient β4 should be negative, reflecting that the firms in distress with fewer investment opportunities reduce the level of investment relative to the investment opportunities. The results show a statistically significant negative relationship between financial distress and the relative investment for firms that have fewer investment opportunities (β4 is negative and statistically different from zero). In this way, firms in financial distress with fewer investment opportunities present a greater propensity to under-invest. According to Hypothesis 1b, the sum of coefficients (β4+β5) should be positive, reflecting that the firms in distress with greater investment opportunities increase the level of investment relative to the investment opportunities. However, the significance test of the sum of coefficients of the interaction variables (β4+β5) is not statistically different from zero. Thus, companies in financial distress which have more investment opportunities show an investment behavior that is not significantly different from that of healthy companies. This assumes that they do not over-invest, but their investment behavior differs from that of the other companies in financial distress. Specifically, for those companies with greater opportunities, the tendency to under-invest disappears, while this tendency remains for firms with fewer investment opportunities.

These results are partially consistent with the theoretical proposals of White (1996), who defended that firms in financial distress could have problems of over- and under-investment. Some papers have addressed this issue indirectly, finding under-investment problems under different circumstances: when ex-ante bankruptcy costs exists (Pindado et al., 2008) or for financially distressed firms if they operate at a loss (Bhagat et al., 2005). Our results add additional evidence supporting the idea that this investment behavior of financially distressed firms is conditioned by their own investment opportunities. In fact, our findings support under-investment but not over-investment behavior.

Regarding the control variables, the results show a positive and statistically significant relationship for cash flow (CF) in models in columns (2) and (3) of Table 5, so that firms with higher cash flow have a greater propensity to over-invest (Jensen, 1986). Lastly, we find that in models in columns (1) and (3) of Table 5 there is a negative relationship between leverage and the level of investment. This result is similar to that obtained by Lang et al. (1996), who found that there is a negative relation between leverage and future growth of the firms.

These results are in line with the proposition of this study, showing that the investment behavior of firms in distress can be conditioned by their investment opportunities. Thus, firms with fewer opportunities have a propensity to under-invest, showing how managers tend to forego profitable projects if it will not provide a result sufficient to avoiding bankruptcy. However, this situation does not hold in the case of companies with more opportunities, since in this case the investment behavior of firms in distress is no different from that of healthy companies.

Robustness tests

In order to control the robustness of the results, we perform two complementary analyses.

In the first one we test model 1, but dividing the sample according to the value of the Tobin's q instead of using an interaction term. So, we test the model considering firms with Q values over and under one, and with Q values over and under the median value of Q. The model follows this specification:

Model 2:

Using this alternative specification, we prevent our results from being biased due to the introduction of an interaction term of two dichotomous variables (QD and DIF) in the original model (model 1). In this case, we use OLS estimation using the Huber/White/sandwich estimator of the variance–covariance matrix, so the test is robust to an unspecified form of heteroscedasticity. We have to use OLS because we split the sample in two different parts, so we do not have consecutive observations for all firms. If GMM panel data were used, we could only analyze firms with at least five consecutive years with Q over or under one (or under or over the median) in each case. Table 6 provides the results of these analyses.

Table 6.

Robustness test (sample divided according to Tobin's q).

  Model 1 (Q>1)Model 1 (Q<1)Model 1 (Q>median)Model 1 (Q<median)
Dependent variable  I/QI/QI/QI/Q
  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef 
CF  0.0137***  0.0020  0.0120***  0.1542***  0.1306**  0.2153***  0.0087***  0.0024  0.0060**  0.1021***  0.0835***  0.1400*** 
  (5.14)  (0.66)  (3.78)  (2.95)  (2.42)  (3.01)  (3.75)  (0.86)  (2.37)  (4.51)  (3.56)  (4.52) 
SIZE  0.0026***  0.0014**  0.0014**  0.0100**  0.0099**  0.0104*  0.0023***  0.0014***  0.0011**  0.0046***  0.0035***  0.0036* 
  (4.98)  (2.53)  (2.27)  (2.53)  (2.45)  (1.93)  (4.81)  (2.81)  (2.01)  (3.50)  (2.65)  (1.96) 
LEV  0.0024  0.0002  0.0040*  0.0143  −0.0079  0.0206  −0.0014  −0.0011  0.0004  −0.0013  −0.0101  0.0065 
  (1.10)  (0.09)  (1.82)  (0.66)  (−0.39)  (0.67)  (−0.80)  (−0.67)  (0.24)  (−0.15)  (−1.23)  (0.55) 
DIF1  −0.0069***      −0.0411***      −0.0009      −0.0187***     
  (−3.88)      (−3.63)      (−0.54)      (−4.63)     
DIF2    −0.0189***      −0.0372***      −0.0101***      −0.0270***   
    (−10.64)      (−3.66)      (−5.81)      (−5.88)   
DIF3      −0.0168***      −0.0527***      −0.0113***      −0.0306*** 
      (−7.08)      (−2.71)      (−5.29)      (−3.95) 
CONSTANT  0.0352***  0.0468***  0.0431***  −0.0065  0.0087  −0.0077  0.0266***  0.0340***  0.0359***  0.0352***  0.0486***  0.0350*** 
  (10.97)  (14.08)  (12.14)  (−0.37)  (0.48)  (−0.39)  (8.99)  (10.91)  (11.09)  (5.17)  (7.14)  (4.79) 
SECTOR  20.40***  16.15***  21.43***  8.04***  9.34***  3.72**  16.55***  13.19***  10.87***  10.08***  13.00***  5.86*** 
COUNTRY  33.63***  29.46***  22.06***  5.67***  6.65***  4.38***  24.96***  23.51***  15.90***  6.10***  5.64***  3.32*** 
YEAR  151.49***  146.12***  147.80***  26.58***  27.21***  29.22***  83.16***  80.83***  88.11***  89.78***  90.95***  89.97*** 
R2  0.07  0.08  0.09  0.08  0.09  0.12  0.07  0.07  0.09  0.08  0.08  0.10 
F  89.23***  94.25***  86.28***  19.16***  18.93***  18.36***  51.16***  52.65***  51.48***  54.57***  55.07***  52.04*** 

SECTOR: Wald's test of the joint significance of the sector's dummy variables. COUNTRY: Wald's test of the joint significance of the country's dummy variables. YEAR: Wald's test of the joint.

Significance of the year's dummy variables. Distributed as a chi-square under the null hypothesis of lack of relationship.

t-Statistic between brackets.

*

A level of significance of 0.1.

**

A level of significance of 0.05.

***

A level of significance of 0.01.

The results are in line with those obtained in our previous analysis. Table 6 shows how the influence of the variable DIF varies according to the value of Tobin's q. The value of the coefficient associated with this variable is negative and significant for both firms with Q values over and under one. However, this negative effect is much more intense for firms with Tobin's q under 1 (the coefficients are from 2 to 6 times more intense depending on the model). When we divide firms according to the median, the differences are even bigger (in this case, even the DIF1 variable is not significant for firms with Q values over the median). According to these results, firms in financial distress with fewer investment opportunities present a greater propensity to under-invest, as we showed in our previous panel data analysis.

The second robustness analysis is performed using the traditional measure of investment over replacement value of assets (I) as dependent variable, dividing the sample in firms with I/Q over and under the median of their industry. This complementary analysis allows us to control that our results are not biased by the way we measure the firm's investment, I/Q, a new measure proposed in this paper. So, we propose the estimation of the following model, using the traditional measure of investment over replacement value of assets (I), and controlling the over and underinvestment situations using two subsamples: one that includes firms with a greater tendency to overinvest, with greater values of I/Q and the other that includes firms with greater a tendency to underinvest, with smaller values of I/Q.

Model 34:

Table 7 provides the results of these analyses.

Table 7.

Robustness test (sample divided according to the over and under investment intensity).

  Model 1 (I/Q>industry)Model 1 (I/Q<industry)
Dependent variable  II
  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef  Coef 
CF  0.0050  0.0220***  0.0163*  0.0619***  0.0593***  0.0776*** 
  (0.73)  (2.95)  (1.92)  (8.74)  (7.24)  (9.10) 
SIZE  0.0038***  0.0042***  0.0071***  0.0044***  0.0049***  0.0046*** 
  (3.54)  (3.88)  (6.28)  (4.37)  (4.87)  (4.14) 
LEV  0.0105**  0.0300***  0.0215***  −0.0162***  −0.0290***  −0.0255*** 
  (2.14)  (6.40)  (4.60)  (−3.58)  (−6.75)  (−6.38) 
DIF1  0.0350***      −0.0244***     
  (11.27)      (−7.23)     
DIF2    0.0317***      −0.0077**   
    (8.26)      (−2.28)   
DIF3      0.0247***      −0.0109** 
      (5.87)      (−2.46) 
CONSTANT  0.1076***  0.0934***  0.0858***  0.0173***  0.0207***  0.0197*** 
  (17.46)  (15.01)  (13.16)  (3.09)  (3.68)  (3.30) 
SECTOR  17.02***  11.87***  12.76***  32.05***  30.22***  16.85*** 
COUNTRY  82.70***  81.79***  85.82***  3.13***  3.80***  5.84*** 
YEAR  7.79***  7.39***  11.02***  41.35***  42.93***  44.40*** 
R2  0.06  0.05  0.06  0.07  0.07  0.09 
F  39.56***  35.86***  38.14***  34.75***  34.68***  35.02*** 

SECTOR: Wald's test of the joint significance of the sector's dummy variables. COUNTRY: Wald's test of the joint significance of the country's dummy variables. YEAR: Wald's test of the joint significance of the year's dummy variables. Distributed as a chi-square under the null hypothesis of lack of relationship.

t-Statistic between brackets.

*

A level of significance of 0.1.

**

A level of significance of 0.05.

***

A level of significance of 0.01.

Table 7 shows the influence of financial distress over investment (using I as dependent variable) for firms according to their tendency to over or under invest (i.e. distinguishing whether their I/Q values are over or under the median of their industry). The results show that, in the group of firms with smaller investment values over Q, the variable DIF is negative and significant, so financially distressed firms in this group present a greater propensity to under-invest. However, for the group of firms with I/Q over the industry median, the variable DIF is positive and statistically significant, so in this group financially distressed firms present a greater propensity to overinvest.

Conclusions

This paper analyzes the influence of financial distress on the investment behavior of companies. The study analyzes the different behavior of firms in financial distress, taking into account the differences that may occur among companies in financial distress depending on their investment opportunities.

The results show that the investment behavior is not uniform for all companies facing financial distress, and the propensity to under-invest depends on the investment opportunities available to the company. Thus, firms with greater opportunities that believe that the additional investments can help them to overcome their difficulties do not show differences with respect to the investment behavior of healthy firms when it comes to taking advantage of investment opportunities. However, managers of companies with fewer investment opportunities have a greater propensity to under-invest because they only implement projects that they consider may prevent the company from having to file for bankruptcy. This behavior makes them miss profitable opportunities that would help improve the situation of the company in distress.

This helps to explain why the reorganization processes undertaken by many firms in distress are often unable to prevent their demise. In this sense, the results are particularly relevant at the present time, in light of the reforms that have occurred in bankruptcy laws in different countries, and the economic crisis, which has increased the number of insolvencies worldwide.

Moreover, future extension of this work could study the effect that the way firms deal with financial distress has on their investment behavior. On the one hand, it might be relevant if firms follow an informal procedure or file for bankruptcy (Aybar Arias et al., 2006; Gilson, 1997; González and González, 2000). On the other hand, firms filing for bankruptcy are affected by different insolvency procedures, because bankruptcy laws vary across countries (Davydenko and Franks, 2008; López Gutiérrez et al., 2012).

Appendix
A.1
Tobin's q

We calculate this ratio following Pindado et al. (2008). They propose different adjustments to improve this measure's precision.

  • MVE: market value of equity

  • MVLTD: market value of long-term debt.

To obtain it, we use the cost of the firm's long-term debt (lit) and the market's long-term interest rates (il). We, therefore, attain a better approximation to the firm's total market value than using the book value of long-term debt (BVLTD).
  • BVSTD: book value of short-term debt

  • K: replacement value of capital.

where TAit is the book value of total assets, BFit the book value of fixed assets and RFit is the replacement value of fixed assets, calculated as follows:
We use the depreciation of firm's assets (δit), the price index variation information (ϕit) and the firm's investment (Iit) to calculate it. This makes it possible to improve the approximation that entails considering the replacement cost as equal to the book value of the firm's assets.

A.2
Investment

The level of investment is measured as follows:

Investment is measured as fixed assets variation between period t and t1, following this expression:

  • NFA: net fixed assets.

  • D: depreciation expenses.

  • K: replacement value of capital.

This measure allows us to control both investment and divestment of distressed firms.

A.3
Cash flows

Cash flow is measured as earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA) over the replacement value of the firm's assets:

A.4
Firms’ size

Firms’ size is measured by the natural logarithm of total assets:

A.5
Firms’ leverage

Degree of the firm's leverage is measured as the ratio of total debt over total assets:

A.6
Financial distress identification
A.6.1
Altman's Z″-Score model

The first financial distress variable (DIF1) is based on Altman's Z″-Score model (Altman, 2002). The Z″-Score model is:

  • X1: working capital to total assets

  • X2: retained earnings to total assets

  • X3: earnings before interest and taxes to total assets

  • X4: market value equity to book value of total liabilities

We identify firms in financial distress when they have Z″-Scores below 1.10.

A.6.2
Financial distress ratio

The second financial distress variable (DIF2) is based on the financial distress ratio (FDR):

  • EBITDA: earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization

  • FE: financial expenses

We consider firms to be in financial distress when they have a financial distress ratio below 1.

A.6.3
Ohlson's model

The third financial distress variable (DIF3) is based on Ohlson's predicted bankruptcy probabilities, p (Ohlson, 1980).

  • SIZE: log of total assets to GNP price-level index ratio

  • TLTA: total liabilities to total assets

  • WCTA: working capital to total assets

  • CLCA: current liabilities to current assets

  • NITA: net income to total assets

  • FUTL: funds from operations to total liabilities

  • INTWO: is equal to one in net income is negative in the previous 2 years or zero otherwise

  • OENEG: is equal to one if total liabilities are greater than total assets or zero otherwise

  • CHIN=(NItNIt−1)/(|NIt||NIt−1|) where NIt is the net income for year t

We identify firms in financial distress when the bankruptcy probability is greater than or equal to 50%.

A.7
Firms’ sector

SECTOR are a set of dummy variables that identify the business activity sector.

A.8
Firms’ country

COUNTRY are a set of dummy variables that identify the country.

A.9
Year

YEAR are a set of dummy variables that identify the year.

References
[Altman, 2002]
E.I. Altman.
Corporate distress prediction models in a turbulent economic and Basel II environment. NYU Working Paper No. FIN-02-052.
(2002),
[Altman, 1968]
E.I. Altman.
Financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy.
J. Finance, 23 (1968), pp. 589-609
[Altman and Hotchkiss, 2006]
E.I. Altman, E. Hotchkiss.
Corporate Financial Distress and Bankruptcy: Predict and Avoid Bankruptcy.
John Wiley & Sons, (2006),
[Andrade and Kaplan, 1998]
G. Andrade, S.N. Kaplan.
How costly is financial (not economic) distress? Evidence from highly leveraged transactions that became distressed.
J. Finance, 53 (1998), pp. 1443-1493
[Arellano and Bond, 1991]
M. Arellano, S. Bond.
Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations.
Rev. Econ. Stud., 58 (1991), pp. 277-297
[Arellano and Bover, 1995]
M. Arellano, O. Bover.
Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-component models.
J. Econometrics, 68 (1995), pp. 29-51
[Asquith et al., 1994]
P. Asquith, R. Gertner, D. Scharfstein.
Anatomy of financial distress: an examination of junk-bond issuers.
Q. J. Econ., 109 (1994), pp. 625-658
[Aybar Arias et al., 2006]
C. Aybar Arias, A. Casino Martínez, J. Lopez Gracia.
La reestructuración financiera de las pymes en crisis. Endogeneidad en la elección entre vía privada y vía concursal.
Investig. Econ., 30 (2006), pp. 137-162
[Azofra Palenzuela et al., 2000]
V. Azofra Palenzuela, P. de Andrés Alonso, J.A. Rodriguez Sanz.
Endeudamiento, oportunidades de crecimiento y estructura contractual: un contraste empírico para el caso español.
Investig. Econ., 24 (2000), pp. 641-679
[Bhagat et al., 2005]
S. Bhagat, N. Moyen, I. Suh.
Investment and internal funds of distressed firms.
J. Corp. Finance, 11 (2005), pp. 449-472
[Blundell and Bond, 1998]
R. Blundell, S. Bond.
Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models.
J. Econometrics, 87 (1998), pp. 115-143
[Cleary, 1999]
S. Cleary.
The relationship between firm investment and financial status.
J. Finance, 54 (1999), pp. 673-692
[Couwenberg, 2001]
O. Couwenberg.
Survival rates in bankruptcy systems: overlooking the evidence.
Eur. J. Law Econ., 12 (2001), pp. 253-273
[Davydenko and Franks, 2008]
S.A. Davydenko, J.R. Franks.
Do bankruptcy codes matter? A study of defaults in France, Germany, and the UK.
J. Finance, 63 (2008), pp. 565-608
[Fazzari et al., 2000]
S.M. Fazzari, R.G. Hubbard, B.C. Petersen.
Investment–cash flow sensitivities are useful: a comment on Kaplan and Zingales.
Q. J. Econ., 115 (2000), pp. 695-705
[Fazzari et al., 1988]
S.M. Fazzari, R.G. Hubbard, B.C. Petersen, A.S. Blinder, J.M. Poterba.
Financing constraints and corporate investment.
Brookings Pap. Econ. Act., (1988), pp. 141-206
[Gilson, 1997]
S.C. Gilson.
Transactions costs and capital structure choice: evidence from financially distressed firms.
J. Finance, 52 (1997), pp. 161-196
[González and González, 2000]
V.M. González, F. González.
Procedimientos de resolución de insolvencia financiera en España: Costes de insolvencia y transferencia de riqueza.
Investig. Econ., 24 (2000), pp. 357-384
[Hoshi et al., 1991]
T. Hoshi, A. Kashyap, D. Scharfstein.
Corporate structure, liquidity, and investment: evidence from Japanese industrial groups.
Q. J. Econ., 106 (1991), pp. 33-60
[Jensen, 1986]
M.C. Jensen.
Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers.
Am. Econ. Rev., 76 (1986), pp. 323-329
[Kadapakkam et al., 1998]
P.R. Kadapakkam, P.C. Kumar, L.A. Riddick.
The impact of cash flows and firm size on investment: the international evidence.
J. Bank. Finance, 22 (1998), pp. 293-320
[Kaplan and Zingales, 2000]
S.N. Kaplan, L. Zingales.
Investment–cash flow sensitivities are not valid measures of financing constraints.
Q. J. Econ., 115 (2000), pp. 707-712
[Kaplan and Zingales, 1997]
S.N. Kaplan, L. Zingales.
Do investment–cash flow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints?.
Q. J. Econ., 112 (1997), pp. 169-215
[Lang et al., 1996]
L. Lang, E. Ofek, R.M. Stulz.
Leverage, investment, and firm growth.
J. Financ. Econ., 40 (1996), pp. 3-29
[López Gutiérrez et al., 2009]
C. López Gutiérrez, M. García Olalla, B. Torre Olmo.
The influence of bankruptcy law on equity value of financially distressed firms: a European comparative analysis.
Int. Rev. Law Econ., 29 (2009), pp. 229-243
[López Gutiérrez et al., 2012]
C. López Gutiérrez, B. Torre Olmo, S. Sanfilippo Azofra.
Firms’ performance under different bankruptcy systems: a Europe-USA empirical analysis.
Account. Finance, 52 (2012), pp. 849-872
[Lopez Iturriaga, 2006]
F.J. Lopez Iturriaga.
Restricciones financieras e inversión en activo fijo: un análisis multivariante.
Span. J. Finance Account./Rev. Esp. Financ. Conta., 35 (2006), pp. 411-436
[Maestro et al., 2007]
M.H. Maestro, A. de Miguel, J. Pindado.
Modelo de inversión basado en la ecuación de Euler con límite máximo de endeudamiento: evidencia empírica internacional.
Cuad. Econ. Dir. Empresa, 10 (2007), pp. 93-127
[Modigliani and Miller, 1958]
F. Modigliani, M.H. Miller.
The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment.
Am. Econ. Rev., 48 (1958), pp. 261-297
[Morgado and Pindado, 2003]
A. Morgado, J. Pindado.
The underinvestment and overinvestment hypotheses: an analysis using panel data.
Eur. Financ. Manage., 9 (2003), pp. 163-177
[Mossman et al., 1998]
C. Mossman, G. Bell, L. Swartz, H. Turtle.
An empirical comparison of bankruptcy models.
Financ. Rev., 33 (1998), pp. 35-54
[Moyen, 2004]
N. Moyen.
Investment–cash flow sensitivities: constrained versus unconstrained firms.
J. Finance, 59 (2004), pp. 2061-2092
[Ohlson, 1980]
J.A. Ohlson.
Financial ratios and the probabilistic prediction of bankruptcy.
J. Account. Res., 18 (1980), pp. 109-131
[Pindado et al., 2008]
J. Pindado, L. Rodrigues, C. De La Torre.
How do insolvency codes affect a firm's investment?.
Int. Rev. Law Econ., 28 (2008), pp. 227-238
[Qian and Strahan, 2007]
J. Qian, P.E. Strahan.
How laws and institutions shape financial contracts: the case of bank loans.
J. Finance, 62 (2007), pp. 2803-2834
[Santos-Pereira and Pires, 2002]
C.M. Santos-Pereira, A.M. Pires.
Detection of outliers in multivariate data: a method based on clustering and robust estimators.
Proceedings in Computational Statistics,
[Whitaker, 1999]
R.B. Whitaker.
The early stages of financial distress.
J. Econ. Finance, 23 (1999), pp. 123-132
[White, 1996]
M.J. White.
The cost of corporate bankruptcy: a US-European comparison.
Corporate Bankruptcy: Economic and Legal Perspectives,
[Whited, 1992]
T.M. Whited.
Debt, liquidity constraints, and corporate investment: evidence from panel data.
J. Finance, 47 (1992), pp. 1425-1460
[Wruck, 1990]
K.H. Wruck.
Financial distress, reorganization, and organizational efficiency.
J. Financ. Econ., 27 (1990), pp. 419-444

To identify financially-constrained firms, some of these papers use dividend payout ratios (Fazzari et al., 1988), and size, based on the notion that smaller firms will be more financially constrained because they face higher informational asymmetry problems and agency costs (Kadapakkam et al., 1998). Another approach used is multivariable analysis, which considers an entire profile of characteristics shared by a particular firm and its dividend payment behavior (Cleary, 1999; Maestro et al., 2007).

The apparent contradiction between these results may be due to the different ways of measuring financial constraints, since they are not directly observable. Replicating these articles with different measures of financial constraints used by previous authors, Moyen (2004) finds that the contradiction in the results can be explained by the way companies are classified in terms of their degree of constraint.

This variable is a good indicator of investment opportunities, since it reflects the market valuation of the capacity of the firm to generate value according to their economic structure (Azofra Palenzuela et al., 2000).

We have to use OLS again, because in this case we have to divide the sample in two subsamples according to their I/Q.

Copyright © 2013. ACEDE
Article options