metricas
covid
Buscar en
European Research on Management and Business Economics
Toda la web
Inicio European Research on Management and Business Economics Entrepreneurial activity and economic growth. A multi-country analysis
Información de la revista
Vol. 26. Núm. 1.
Páginas 9-17 (enero - abril 2020)
Compartir
Compartir
Descargar PDF
Más opciones de artículo
Visitas
1857
Vol. 26. Núm. 1.
Páginas 9-17 (enero - abril 2020)
Open Access
Entrepreneurial activity and economic growth. A multi-country analysis
Visitas
1857
Manuel Almodóvar-Gonzáleza, Antonio Fernández-Portilloa, Juan Carlos Díaz-Caserob
a Departamento de Economía Financiera y Contabilidad, Universidad de Extremadura, Cáceres, Spain
b Departamento de Organización de Empresas, Universidad de Extremadura, Cáceres, Spain
Este artículo ha recibido

Under a Creative Commons license
Información del artículo
Resumen
Texto completo
Bibliografía
Descargar PDF
Estadísticas
Figuras (5)
Mostrar másMostrar menos
Tablas (6)
Table 1. Different directions of the causality of the entrepreneurial activity-economic growth relationship.
Table 2. 10 areas of WDI, number of variables and number of simplified variables.
Table 3. Cubic regression GDP/TEA and annual minimum*.
Table 4. Summary of criteria.
Table 5. Summary of results in developing countries.
Table 6. Summary of results of developed countries.
Mostrar másMostrar menos
Abstract

Most scientific literature assumes that entrepreneurial activity, in a broad sense, is positive for economic growth. Our work analyses 74 economies in a period of 6 years, identifying those factors related simultaneously with an entrepreneurial spirit and economic growth. The results enable to know the impact of a specific factor on entrepreneurship and economic growth. Additionally, we suggest that entrepreneurial activity plays a different role depending on the economic stage of the country in question. On the other hand, less developed countries should not be based on generic entrepreneurship if the objective they pursue is to promote economic growth.

Keywords:
Entrepreneurial activity
Entrepreneurship
Economic growth
Developing countries
Developed countries
JEL classifications:
O1
O4
L26
Texto completo
1Introduction

There is a certain scientific consensus that the entrepreneurial activity, in some of its manifestations, is related to economic growth (Almodovar-Gonzalez, Sanchez-Escobedo, & Fernandez-Portillo, 2019; García-Rodríguez, Gil-Soto, Ruiz-Rosa, & Gutiérrez-Taño, 2017; Gómez-Gras, Mira-Solves, & Martínez-Mateo, 2011; Hormiga, Batista-Canino, & Sánchez-Medina, 2011). But this relationship, far from being clear (Carree & Thurik, 2008), has not achieved satisfactory models (Liñán & Fernández-Serrano, 2014), and poses several challenges to the academic world.

Perhaps, the most unknown thing about this relationship is projected on the causality between the variables involved, since "the causality between entrepreneurship and economic growth has not been established conclusively" (Valliere & Peterson, 2009:460).

To this, we must add that, in addition to economic growth and entrepreneurial activity, some many factors or variables come into play (Carree, Van Stel, Thurik, & Wennekers, 2007), and that these factors are established by researchers based on the macroeconomic theory.

In this sense, our research aims to establish an empirical model that allows for the interpretation of results from the different theories of economic growth, and from different approaches to the causality between economic growth and entrepreneurial spirit, without making any assumption about the direction between the variables.

We also want to point out that this work is based on the concept of generic entrepreneurship understood as "Any action intended to start a business, regardless of its features, not related to any specific type of entrepreneurship" (Almodóvar, 2018:226)

To do so, before defining our objectives, we synthesized two groups of main problems. The first problem is the assumption of the productivity of the entrepreneurial activity, which includes two aspects: the acceptance that generic entrepreneurship always has positive effects (Fadahunsi & Rosa, 2002; Audretsch, 2009), and the position of certain academics who deny this statement (Liñán & Fernández-Serrano, 2014; Schott & Jensen, 2008; Valliere & Peterson, 2009; Wong, Ho, & Autio, 2005). In many cases, researchers assume the positive effects of entrepreneurship, without taking into account the existence of destructive entrepreneurship (Desai, Acs, & Weitzel, 2013).

The second problem is Entrepreneurial activity based on the stage of economic development of the countries, which refers to the existing dichotomy between those researchers who defend the creation of companies to achieve economic objectives in developing countries, and those who oppose that position. These approaches suggests that for developed countries, entrepreneurship has a positive impact, which is measured by economic growth (Audretsch, 2012), and in countries with negative development (Acs & Varga, 2005; Sautet, 2013; Van Stel, Carree, & Thurik, 2005; Wennekers, Van Stel, Thurik, & Reynolds, 2005).

Given these scientific debates, we have the following research questions: (a) Is generic entrepreneurial activity related to economic growth?, and, (b) from economic growth, should the generic entrepreneurial activity be encouraged in developing countries, bearing in mind that some authors point to a different impact depending on the type of economy, in particular, a negative impact in developing countries?

Therefore, based on the problems defined and on the research questions posed, two objectives are established: Objective 1: To study the possible existence of factors related to generic entrepreneurial activity and economic growth. Objective 2: To study the possible difference in the economic impact of entrepreneurial activity between economies, especially the possible existence of factors positively related to generic entrepreneurial activity and economic growth.

As key contributions of our research we can highlight the convenience of encouraging generic entrepreneurship in advanced economies, and the inconvenience of increasing generic entrepreneurial activity in the most disadvantaged economies are confirmed. Also, there are signs of a possible endogeneity of the entrepreneurial spirit to economic growth in developing countries.

Furthermore, two new approaches are used: First, the classification of the economic stage of each country is made based on the entrepreneurial impact instead of on the income level. And second, the statistical model is not restrictive regarding the causality of the variables, that is, it can be interpreted that entrepreneurship depends on economic growth and vice versa.

After this introduction, a theoretical framework of analysis is established, the methodology used is defined, the results are presented and a discussion and conclusions have presented that cover the limitations and future lines of research.

2Entrepreneurial activity and economic growth2.1Relationship between entrepreneurial activity and economic growth

A common error in the study of entrepreneurship is the acceptance that its effects in economic terms are always positive. In many cases, researchers assume the positive effects without taking into account that these activities can also be destructive (Desai et al., 2013).

In this sense, Audretsch (2009) emphasises how public powers encouraging entrepreneurship without solid evidence to justify it. In this desire, they are only concerned with promoting entrepreneurship, without taking into account the type of activity, which can lead to unexpected results (Fadahunsi & Rosa, 2002).

Generic entrepreneurship is not the same as the specific types of entrepreneurial activity. Following this investigation, studies such as those by Liñán and Fernández-Serrano (2014), show a negative relationship when comparing generic entrepreneurship (measured by the TEA variable of the GEM project) with economic growth, and yet specific business initiatives (based on opportunity) can be associated with higher income levels. Wong et al. (2005) find evidence of the existence of activities that do not contribute to the economy, where only new high potential companies show a significant impact on economic growth. In the same vein, Valliere and Peterson (2009) attribute an impact on economic growth (in developed countries) only to high expectation entrepreneurs.

As research suggests, new activities based on necessity are located more intensely in the weakest economies, while in developed economies there are more initiatives based on opportunity. The literature indicates a relationship between the type of economy and the type of business that is created: opportunity-driven entrepreneurs prevail in high-income countries, while those based on necessity predominate in low-income countries (Amorós, Fernández, & Tapia, 2012). As indicated by Larroulet and Couyoumdjian (2009), advanced economies have low total entrepreneurship rates, but a higher rate of entrepreneurship based on opportunity compared to necessity. On the contrary, less developed countries have higher rates of total entrepreneurial activity, although the relative presence of entrepreneurship based on opportunity is lower. Acs and Varga (2005), find that opportunity has a significant positive effect on economic development, while new activities based on necessity do not affect. Aparicio, Urbano, and Audretsch (2016) find a positive relationship between new business based on opportunity and economic growth, indicating that activities based on necessity have no long-term effect on economic growth. In short, progress towards development represents moving away from entrepreneurship based on necessity (Sautet, 2013).

Why are the type of entrepreneurial activity and economic growth related? Research suggests that the answer lies in the quality of entrepreneurship. Anokhin and Wincent (2012) point out that opportunities differ between developing and developed countries, and for the latter, the initiatives are of higher quality (Shane, 2009). The point of greatest consensus is about the lack of impact of entrepreneurship based on necessity (Valliere & Peterson, 2009) and that it does not manage to boost economic growth (Sautet, 2013).

On another front, differentiating between the exogenous variable in the relationship between entrepreneurship and economic growth is a challenge which scientific research continues to face. This is why Valliere and Peterson (2009: 460) maintain that "the causality between entrepreneurship and economic growth has not been conclusively established". Given this ambiguity, opposing positions arise.

Authors such as Acs, Audretsch, Braunerhjelm, and Carlsson (2012: 297) state that "the results have proven to be remarkably robust concerning the impact of entrepreneurship on economic growth". On the other hand, researchers such as Fritsch and Schroeter (2011) propose that the level of economic development leads to the creation of companies, which is justified because the opportunities and the expected rewards are greater. In the work by Koellinger and Thurik (2012) it is shown that entrepreneurship can be a consequence of economic growth.

Finally, the idea of a double causality is also expressed. Amorós et al. (2012) point out a reciprocal relationship, where the state of development stimulates new economic activities and the creation of companies contributes to development. Besides, Aparicio et al. (2016) state that there is a feedback effect between them. In short, these contradictions reinforce the words of Carree and Thurik (2008), who state that the relationship is unclear.

In practice, different examples that assume the causality in both directions can be found, some of which are listed in Table 1.

Table 1.

Different directions of the causality of the entrepreneurial activity-economic growth relationship.

Authors  Independent variable  Dependent variable 
Van Stel et al. (2005)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Wong et al. (2005)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Wennekers et al. (2005): Creating U curve  Economic growth  Entrepreneurship 
Carree et al. (2007): Several models  Economic growth  Entrepreneurship 
Wennekers et al. (2007)  Economic growth  Entrepreneurship 
Carree and Thurik (2008)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Valliere and Peterson (2009)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Pinillos and Reyes (2011)  Economic growth  Entrepreneurship 
Acs et al. (2012)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Van Praag and Van Stel (2013)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Liñán, Fernández-Serrano, and Romero (2013)  Economic growth  Entrepreneurship 
Liñán and Fernández-Serrano (2014)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Galindo and Méndez (2014): Double causality  Econ.growth/Entrepreneurship  Econ. growth/Entrepreneurship 
Dau and Cuervo-Cazurra (2014)  Economic growth  Entrepreneurship 
Urbano and Aparicio (2016)  Entrepreneurship  Economic growth 
Source: Compiled by the authors
2.2Difference in the impact of entrepreneurship depending on the development stage

The difference in the impact of entrepreneurship depending on the economic stage is statistically based on the direct U adjustment. (Wennekers et al., 2005). Its application to the entrepreneurship-economic growth relationship will support that the first part of the function will show an inverse relationship between new economic activities and economic growth, and a second part with a direct relationship.

The empirical evidence shows the dynamics of entrepreneurship differs among the stages of development (Amorós et al., 2012; Urbano & Aparicio, 2016). U curve implies a negative (or null) impact of entrepreneurship on less developed economies and positive on developed ones (Van Stel et al., 2005; Wennekers et al., 2005). Also, it reflects how entrepreneurship is greater in developing countries compared to developed ones (Acs & Amorós, 2008; Carree et al., 2007; Van Stel et al., 2005).

Academics provides several explanations for this. For example, Díaz, Almodóvar, Sánchez, Coduras, and Hernández (2013) explain the "U" function under the prism of institutional quality and the stages of Porter, Sachs, and McArthur (2002). In factor-driven, a negative relationship between entrepreneurship and institutional quality is produced. In the efficiency-driven stage, activities motivated by necessity are abandoned. Finally, in the innovation-driven stage, where a legal framework has been consolidated, together with new business opportunities, an increase in the creation of companies is produced.

Other authors use types of entrepreneurial activity (opportunity-necessity). For example, Liñán and Fernández-Serrano (2014) argue that wealthy countries offer more opportunities. Sautet (2013) also explains the U curve going from necessity (developing countries) to opportunity (typical of developed countries).

3Conceptual model and hypotheses3.1Approach

We aim to approach the problem of the relationship between entrepreneurship and economic growth without directly confronting the direction of causality. Thus, the approach seeks the connection at the origin and focuses on the factors that jointly determine both entrepreneurial activity and economic growth, so if the same factor boosted entrepreneurship and economic growth, both would be related (see Fig. 1). The key would be to find factors that have a common influence between the two variables mentioned, that is, that they serve as a link under their reciprocal influence, both on entrepreneurship and economic growth.

Fig. 1.

Factors, entrepreneurship and economic growth.

(0,1MB).
Source: Own source

Based on this approach, the two proposed objectives were established. In the first place, and without assuming their existence, the possibility of there being factors that are related (positively or negatively) simultaneously to the two variables is explored. If objective one is fulfilled, we move on to the next one, specifically, to study the possibility of a differentiated impact of entrepreneurship on economic growth depending on the stage of economic development of the country (see Fig. 2), with emphasis on the exploration of some factor that can promote entrepreneurship in a productive way.

Fig. 2.

Analysis depending on the development stage.

(0,14MB).
Source: Own source
3.2Hypotheses

As stated, the assumptions of the approach are conditional and need to be refuted, and therefore, our hypotheses study the possible existence of these factors reciprocally related to economic growth and entrepreneurial activity.

Therefore, having raised the first research problem, we question whether the generic entrepreneurial activity is related to economic growth (Gómez-Gras et al., 2011; Hormiga et al., 2011; Wennekers et al., 2005) through the first hypothesis:

H1: There are factors with a reciprocal relationship between entrepreneurial activity (generic) and economic growth.

To study objective 2, we state 2 hypotheses, which represent the two sides of the same coin, so that they are stated in the following way:

H2a: In developing countries, factors related to entrepreneurial (generic) activity have a negative impact on economic growth.

As indicated by part of the literature, entrepreneurship has a negative impact on economic growth in developing countries (Acs & Varga, 2005; Sautet, 2013; Van Stel et al., 2005; Wennekers et al., 2005), so it can be assumed that those factors (independent variables) that encourage entrepreneurship will hinder economic growth, and those factors that have a negative impact on the number of activities, will improve economic growth. Note that if hypothesis 2a is not fulfilled, it is because some factor (independent variable) with the capacity to promote the creation of companies in a productive way (in terms of economic growth) has been identified, in other words, if the hypothesis is fulfilled it is because all the possible factors that support the emergence of new businesses will generate an economic decline (and vice versa).

H2b: In developed countries, the factors related to entrepreneurial activity (generic) impact in the same direction on economic growth.

If entrepreneurship has a positive impact in developed countries (Wennekers et al., 2005; Acs & Varga, 2005; Audretsch, 2012), it can be assumed that those factors (independent variables) that promote entrepreneurship also promote economic growth, and those factors that have a negative impact on entrepreneurship, will also have it on economic growth.

4Methodology4.1Source of data and variables

We use two dependent variables. Fist, entrepreneurial activity, measured by the Total Early-stage Entrepreneurial Activity (TEA) from GEM, which is an aggregate variable at national level that reflects the percentage of the population between 18–64 years that claims to be involved in an entrepreneurial initiative of any kind, which does not exceed 42 months of activity. Second, economic growth, measured by Gross Domestic Product per capita in purchasing power parity in US dollars at current prices in dollars (GDP ppp current $). It was obtained from the World Development Indicators (WDI). It is defined as the GDP in terms of population, calculated without taking into account depreciation and denominated in current US dollars.

The independent variables were obtained from the World Bank database (WDI), which is available for 153 countries and consists of 1195 variables. The variables are divided into 10 large areas, which are listed in Table 2, together with their description and the number of initial variables that the database contains and those that were finally left for our investigation once a series of criteria that eliminated redundant variables were applied or that were outside the scope of this investigation. Altogether there were 524 left.

Table 2.

10 areas of WDI, number of variables and number of simplified variables.

  Education  Environment.  Economic Policy and debt  Financial sector  Health  Infrastructure  Work and social protection  Poverty  Private sector and trade  Public sector  Total 
Initial  89  140  432  49  94  55  93  18  147  78  1195 
Final  31  59  93  45  41  37  29  13  127  49  524 
Source: Prepared by the authors based on http://datacatalog.worldbank.org/ and http://www.socialexplorer.com/

The sample includes all countries with available data (74 economies) for the variables of a period of 6 years. Each statistical case refers to a country in a specific year. A total of 248 cases are formed, representing all the countries that have participated in the GEM project from 2004 to 2009, except Puerto Rico in 2007 and the Palestinian Territories in 2009 (no data for GDP).

Once the sample size was indicated, the sample universe in 1128 cases, (188 countries adhered to the World Bank for 6 years) was estimated. We classify the countries into 2 groups according to the relationship shown between GDP and TEA. If it is inverse (the higher the GDP the lower the TEA) they are included in group 1 (C1 according to our notation), if it is direc,t they are included in group 2 (C2). Thus, we interpret the concept of a developed economy as that characterized by a productive entrepreneurial activity (in terms of economic growth) and developing economies by unproductive entrepreneurship.

We start with the GDP/TEA curve, and annually, we discriminate depending on the position they occupy concerning the inflexion point. The cases located to the left of the minimum show an inverse relationship and are part of C1, the cases to the right, with a direct GDP/ TEA ratio, are included in C2.

In Figs. 3 and 4, we can see how the classification would be in two groups for a given year. At a conceptual level, the fact of having divided it into two groups allows us to interpret the cubic model in two lines (Fig. 4): one with an inverse relationship (C1) and the other one with a direct relationship (C2).

Fig. 3.

Classification in 2009.

Own source

(0,05MB).
Fig. 4.

Cubic and linear model GDP/TEA.

Own source

(0,1MB).

Once the economies are classified with these parameters (Table 3), we can divide the 248 statistical cases into a developing and developed economies. Note that each statistical case represents a country for a year, so their classification can vary from one year to the next. If we contrast the resulting classification with the classification of the Global Competitiveness Report, we observe a coincidence of more than 99%.

Table 3.

Cubic regression GDP/TEA and annual minimum*.

YearRegressionParametersMinimum
R2  gl1  gl2  Sig.  b0  b1  b2  b3 
2004  0.625  16.69  30  0.000  3.81E+01  −3.69E-03  1.30E-07  −1.40E-12  22356.10 
2005  0.347  5.50  31  0.004  2.51E+01  −1.89E-03  5.71E-08  −5.08E-13  24709.71 
2006  0.466  11.04  38  0.000  2.59E+01  −1.79E-03  4.89E-08  −4.07E-13  28140.13 
2007  0.441  9.74  37  0.000  2.50E+01  −1.47E-03  3.49E-08  −2.48E-13  31990.28 
2008  0.525  14.38  39  0.000  2.69E+01  −1.67E-03  4.15E-08  −3.10E-13  30613.75 
2009  0.577  22.25  49  0.000  2.65E+01  −1.72E-03  4.29E-08  −3.11E-13  29491.27 

*Each year the cubic curve is calculated, as well as the annual minimum.

*We calculate the regression between TEA and GDP, where the coefficients b represent the estimated parameters. The annual minimum is obtained by making the first derivative equal to zero and verifying that the value of the second one is greater than zero.

Source: Compiled by the authors.

The empirical study is based on the pooled analysis with Ordinary Least Squares, which will be used to estimate the seven years together. Even though this analysis has a limitation, a statistic that specifies the possibility of bias due to unobservable heterogeneity, there are examples of its application in the literature (Wennekers, Thurik, Van Stel, & Noorderhaven, 2007 or Díaz et al., 2013). In addition to the criteria, stricter than usual, established by Díaz et al. (2013), we added some additional criteria, thus being more demanding regarding the firmness and representativeness of the regressions from year to year. The five established criteria are summarized in Table 4.

Table 4.

Summary of criteria.

  GDP  TEA 
Independent variable  R-pooled>0.2 (α=0.01)n-pooled of R: n>75% total casesSign R2-pooled= Sign of R2i,, …, R2j; i=2004 j=2009R2i>0,, …, R2j>0; i=2004 j=2009R2-adjusted pooled>0,15 (α=0.01)  R-pooled>0.2 (α=0.01)n-pooled of R: n>75% total casesSign R2-pooled= Sign of R2i,, …, R2j; i=2004 j=2009R2i>0,, …, R2j>0; i=2004 j=2009R2-adjusted pooled>0,15 (α=0.01) 
Source: Compiled by the authors.

This work carries out 2096 regressions, because 524 dependent variables are used, which were regressed once for the TEA, and another time for the GDP. This process is done twice, once for developing country economies, and once for developed countries.

5Results

Of the 524 independent variables considered (factors), we find several that have exceeded the statistical model, in particular, 44 variables, which will be considered as factors with simultaneous influence on economic growth and entrepreneurship. Of these factors, 37 appear in developing countries and 7 in developed countries (see Fig. 5).

Fig. 5.

Variables of results by groups.

(0,42MB).
Source: Compiled by the authors

Based on these data, it should be pointed out that regarding the first objective, the existence of factors with a reciprocal relationship between the entrepreneurial activity and economic growth is confirmed, so we accept hypothesis 1.

The second objective has been confirmed, as we observe a different functioning, analysed through factors, of the entrepreneurship-growth relationship depending on the economic stage.

In short, we have found a relationship between entrepreneurship and economic growth through factors, but these behave differently depending on the economy in which they are applied. Besides, and because of the performance observed in developing countries, we have not been able to identify the existence of factors positively related to generic entrepreneurship and economic growth, which, according to our research, we did not find variables with which to promote entrepreneurship productively in these economies.

The results summarized in Table 5, indicate that none of the variables of the model in group 1 maintains a relationship in the same direction with the GDP and the TEA, that is, if the relationship of a variable is inverse with the GDP, it will be direct with the TEA (and vice versa). Thus, we are in a position to accept that in developing countries the factors related to entrepreneurial activity impact on economic growth in a different direction (Hypothesis 2a).

Table 5.

Summary of results in developing countries.

Area  Independent variable  Dependent  Relationship 
EducationStudent-teacher ratio, primary level  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
School enrolment, secondary level (gross %)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
School enrolment, tertiary level (gross %)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
EnvironmentElectricity consumption (Kw/h per capita)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Energy use (kg of equivalent oil per capita)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Growth of the urban population (annual %)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Economic policy and debtFinal consumption expenditure of the general government  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Services, etc., added value (% of GDP)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
InfrastructureSubscribers to fixed broadband (per 100 people)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Internet users (per 100 people)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Subscriptions of cell phones (per 100 people)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Motor vehicles (per 1000 inhabitants)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Private vehicles (per 1000 inhabitants)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Road sector (roads) diesel fuel consumption per capita (kg oil equival.)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Telephone lines (per 100 inhabitants)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
HealthFertility rate in adolescents (birth per 1,000 women aged 15 and 19)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Inactivity rate by ages, people aged 65 and over (% of working-age)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Inactivity rate by ages, people under 15 (% of working-age population)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Birth rate, live births in one year (per 1,000 people)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Fertility rate, total (birth number per woman)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Health expenditure per capita, PPA (2005 constant international US$)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Health expenditure, public sector (% of GDP)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Population aged between 0 and 14 (% of total)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Population aged 65 and over (% of total)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Population growth (annual %)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Work and social protectionJobs in industry (% of total jobs)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Vulnerable employment, total (% of total employment)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Wage earners, total (% of total hired)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Private sector and tradeConsolidated rate, simple average, all the products (%)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Consolidated rated, simple average, manufactured products (%)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Consolidated rated, simple average, primary products (%)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Merchandise exported to developing economies in Europe and Central Asia (% of total merchandise exported)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Share of tariff lines with specific rates, all the products (%)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Share of tariff lines with specific rates, primary products (%)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Public sectorCustoms and other taxes on imports (% of tax revenue)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Direct 
Expenditure (% of GDP)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 
Collection, excluding donations (% of GDP)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Inverse 

In the same way, and based on the results summarised in Table 6, we observe that none of the variables of the model in group 2 maintains a relationship in a different direction with GDP and TEA, that is, if the relationship of a variable is inverse with the GDP, it is also reverse with the TEA and vice versa.

Table 6.

Summary of results of developed countries.

Area  Independent variable  Dependent  Relationship 
Education  Public expenditure on education, total (% of government expenditure)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Direct 
HealthInactivity rate by ages, people aged 60 and over (% of working-age)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Inverse 
Population aged 60 and over (% of total)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Inverse 
Work and social protectionRelationship between employment and population, aged over 15, tot.(%)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Direct 
Active population rate, total (% of total population aged over 15)  GDP/TEA  Direct/Direct 
Long-term unemployment (% of total unemployment)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Inverse 
Private sector and trade  Procedures to register a property (number)  GDP/TEA  Inverse/Inverse 
Links
Research card
Universe  Possible cases: 1128. Calculated from the 188 countries adhered to the World Bank, during a period equivalent to that of our study (6 years) 
Geographical area  74 countries 
Geographical level  Spatial delimitation is done at country level 
Time range  6 years. Period: 2004-2009 
Sample unit  Each statistical case is formed with a country (Ci) in a year (Cn). Ci, Yn i=1,…, 75 n=2004,…,2009. 
Sample design  All data available of the participating countries in GEM 2004-2009Exceptions due to lack of data in the independent variables:
  • -

    Puerto Rico in 2007

  • -

    Palestinian Territories in 2009

 
Sample size  248 cases. Formed by the binomial country/year 
Sample distribution  139 cases for developing economies109 cases for advanced economies 
Sample error  5,5% for a confidence level of 95% and a heterogeneity of 50% 
Collection method  Secondary data (from GEM and IDM) 
Data access  August 2011 
Estimation model  OLS pooled regression. Increased criteria of Díaz et al. (2013) 
Dependent variablesEntrepreneurship: TEA of the GEM project 
Economic growth: GDP pc PPP (IDM) World Bank 
Independent variables  524 variables. 10 areas (HDI) of the World Bank 
Analysis software  IBM SPSS Statistics 21 and Derive 5.0 
Source: Compiled by the authors

Therefore, we accept that in developed countries the factors related to the entrepreneurial activity impact on economic growth in the same direction (hypothesis 2b).

Finally, and once the acceptances of hypotheses H2a and H2b have been discussed, it can be said that objective 2 has been partially achieved, in the sense that we can study the possible difference in the economic impact of entrepreneurial activity between economies (first part of objective 2), but we have not been able to identify the second part of the objective that referred especially to the possible existence of factors positively related to generic entrepreneurial activity and economic growth.

6Discussion and conclusions

Our results indicate, on the one hand, the existence of a relationship between entrepreneurship and economic growth, and on the other hand, differentiated behaviour between developed economies and developing economies.

The fact that in the environment of advanced countries, what drives entrepreneurship is also economically beneficial, and that in the context of the poorest countries, if a factor intensifies entrepreneurial activity, it slows down economic growth, in principle it shows that promoting entrepreneurship is not relevant for developing countries, though for developed countries it is.

The proposal that entrepreneurial activity is positive in developed countries and negative in developing countries should always be interpreted with the adjective generic. Thus, our work does not contradict those who defend entrepreneurship based on an opportunity in less advanced countries (Amorós et al., 2012; Aparicio et al., 2016), since this entrepreneurial initiative is a specific category, so it is not generic.

It is true, and it may be an explanation for our results, that generic entrepreneurial activity has a stronger necessity component in developing countries, and of opportunity in developed countries (Amorós et al., 2012; Larroulet & Couyoumdjian, 2009; Valliere & Peterson, 2009), having the former negative consequences (Sautet, 2013) and the latter positive consequences (Aparicio et al., 2016).

The results in developing countries seem to be describing the environmental factors of the GEM growth model (Kelley, Bosma, & Amorós, 2011). On the other hand, the explanation of the influence of these factors in developing countries is easily explained from economic growth, but difficult to explain from the entrepreneurial activity one. We want to express that our results raise the possibility of a relationship of dependence of entrepreneurship on economic growth in developing countries, which could be explained by the levels of necessity for entrepreneurial activity. These levels are higher in developing countries formed by basic subsistence companies (Valliere & Peterson, 2009), and show zero economic growth (Acs, Desai, & Hessels, 2008; Aparicio et al., 2016). It is no coincidence that the decreasing part of "U" can be explained by a high prevalence of necessity entrepreneurs in the most disadvantaged economies (Valliere & Peterson, 2009). We add a passive character of entrepreneurship based on the necessity to these statements since it is not a decision that is made between two alternatives but represents the only possible option in the absence of work. In other words, it is a business initiative motivated by the economic situation, and that is why we suggest the possibility of entrepreneurship in the face of economic growth in developing countries.

In developed countries there is a debate about whether to consider growth as exogenous (Dau & Cuervo-Cazurra, 2014; Wennekers et al., 2007), or to consider entrepreneurship exogenous (Carree & Thurik, 2008; Liñán & Fernández-Serrano, 2014), and even the possibility of double causality (Aparicio et al., 2016; Galindo & Méndez, 2014).

In any case, our study suggests that boosting new businesses is not always appropriate in less developed countries if the objective is to favour economic growth. In this line, we find support in those authors who discourage promoting entrepreneurial activity in less favoured economies (Anokhin & Wincent, 2012; Valliere & Peterson, 2009) and propose to focus on the exploitation of economies of scale, the attraction of foreign investment, or the development of human capital. By contrast, for developed countries, generic entrepreneurial activity is related to economic growth, and its promotion is useful to increase the wealth of a country.

As indicated, in this sense there are opposing positions that suggest the possibility that under certain circumstances, even in development contexts, generic entrepreneurship may not be as good as some public authorities have assumed (Audrestsch, 2009).

The prime implication that emerges from our work consists of the usefulness of measuring the impact of new businesses, based on the fact that the impact in terms of national wealth is not always positive. On the other hand, and contrary to what could be interpreted by our conclusions, academics should not rule out promoting new activities as a means to achieve economic growth in poorer countries, where certain specific forms of qualitative nature must be promoted, give rise to a smaller number of businesses, but of higher quality.

We specifically identify the following limitations: (a) the use of a statistical model based on pooled regressions has unobservable heterogeneity problems. However, when using the pooled model used by Díaz et al. (2013), which mitigated this problem, and adding some additional criteria to this model; (b) there is a problem derived from the use of the "U" model, which is the interpretation of results in economies that are close to the turning point of the curve, so for these types of countries, our recommendations should be taken with caution; and (c) this work does not analyse time delays.

References
[Acs and Amorós, 2008]
Z.J. Acs, J.E. Amorós.
Entrepreneurship and competitiveness dynamics in Latin America.
Small Business Economics, 31 (2008), pp. 305-323
[Acs and Varga, 2005]
Z.J. Acs, A. Varga.
Entrepreneurship, agglomeration and technological change.
Small Business Economics, 24 (2005), pp. 323-334
[Acs et al., 2012]
Z.J. Acs, D.B. Audretsch, P. Braunerhjelm, B. Carlsson.
Growth and entrepreneurship.
Small Business Economics, 39 (2012), pp. 289-300
[Acs et al., 2008]
Z.J. Acs, S. Desai, J. Hessels.
Entrepreneurship, economic development and institutions.
Small Business Economics, 31 (2008), pp. 219-234
[Almodóvar, 2018]
M. Almodóvar.
Tipo de emprendimiento y fase de desarrollo como factores clave para el resultado de la actividad emprendedora.
Cuadernos de Relaciones Laborales, 36 (2018), pp. 225-244
[Almodovar-Gonzalez et al., 2019]
M. Almodovar-Gonzalez, M.C. Sanchez-Escobedo, A. Fernandez-Portillo.
Linking demographics, entrepreneurial activity, and economic growth.
Revista ESPACIOS, 40 (2019),
[Amorós et al., 2012]
J.E. Amorós, C. Fernández, J. Tapia.
Quantifying the relationship between entrepreneurship and competitiveness development stages in Latin America.
International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 8 (2012), pp. 249-270
[Anokhin and Wincent, 2012]
S. Anokhin, J. Wincent.
Start-up rates and innovation: A cross-country examination.
Journal of Business Venturing, 43 (2012), pp. 41-60
[Aparicio et al., 2016]
S. Aparicio, D. Urbano, D.B. Audretsch.
Institutional factors, opportunity entrepreneurship and economic growth: Panel data evidence.
Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 102 (2016), pp. 45-46
[Audretsch, 2009]
D.B. Audretsch.
The entrepreneurial society.
Journal of Technology Transfer, 34 (2009), pp. 245-254
[Audretsch, 2012]
D.B. Audretsch.
Entrepreneurship research.
Management Decision, 50 (2012), pp. 755-764
[Carree et al., 2007]
M.A. Carree, A. Van Stel, A.R. Thurik, S. Wennekers.
The relationship between economic development and business ownership revisited.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 19 (2007), pp. 281-291
[Carree and Thurik, 2008]
M.A. Carree, A.R. Thurik.
The lag structure of the impact of business ownership on economic performance in OECD countries.
Small Business Economics, 30 (2008), pp. 101-110
[Dau and Cuervo-Cazurra, 2014]
L.A. Dau, A. Cuervo-Cazurra.
To formalize or not to formalize: Entrepreneurship and pro-market institutions.
Journal of Business Venturing, 29 (2014), pp. 668-687
[Desai et al., 2013]
S. Desai, Z.J. Acs, U. Weitzel.
A model of destructive entrepreneurship: Insight for conflict and postconflict recovery.
The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57 (2013), pp. 20-40
[Díaz et al., 2013]
J.C. Díaz, M. Almodóvar, M.C. Sánchez, A. Coduras, R. Hernández.
Institutional variables, entrepreneurial activity and economic development.
Management Decision, 51 (2013), pp. 281-305
[Fadahunsi and Rosa, 2002]
A. Fadahunsi, P. Rosa.
Entrepreneurship and illegality: Insights from the Nigerian cross-border trade.
Journal of Business Venturing, 17 (2002), pp. 397-429
[Fritsch and Schroeter, 2011]
M. Fritsch, A. Schroeter.
Why does the effect of new business formation differ across regions?.
Small Business Economics, 36 (2011), pp. 383-400
[García-Rodríguez et al., 2017]
F. García-Rodríguez, E. Gil-Soto, I. Ruiz-Rosa, D. Gutiérrez-Taño.
Entrepreneurial potential in less innovative regions: the impact of social and cultural environment.
European Journal of Management and Business Economics, 26 (2017), pp. 163-179
[Galindo and Méndez, 2014]
M.A. Galindo, M.A. Méndez.
Entrepreneurship, economic growth, and innovation: Are feedback effects at work?.
Journal of Business Research, 67 (2014), pp. 825-830
[Gómez-Gras et al., 2011]
J.M. Gómez-Gras, I. Mira-Solves, J. Martínez-Mateo.
Determinants of entrepreneurship: An overview.
International Journal of Business Environment, 3 (2011), pp. 1-14
[Hormiga et al., 2011]
E. Hormiga, R.M. Batista-Canino, A. Sánchez-Medina.
The role of intellectual capital in the success of new ventures.
International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 7 (2011), pp. 71-92
[Kelley et al., 2011]
D. Kelley, N.S. Bosma, J.E. Amorós.
Global entrepreneurship monitor 2010 global report.
Global Entrepreneurship Research Association (GERA), (2011),
[Koellinger and Thurik, 2012]
P. Koellinger, A.R. Thurik.
Entrepreneurship and the business cycle.
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 94 (2012), pp. 1143-1156
[Larroulet and Couyoumdjian, 2009]
C. Larroulet, J.P. Couyoumdjian.
Entrepreneurship and Growth A Latin American Paradox?.
Independent Review, 14 (2009), pp. 81-100
[Liñán and Fernández-Serrano, 2014]
F. Liñán, J. Fernández-Serrano.
National culture, entrepreneurship and economic development: Different patterns across the European Union.
Small Business Economics, 42 (2014), pp. 685-702
[Liñán et al., 2013]
F. Liñán, J. Fernández-Serrano, I. Romero.
Necessity and opportunity entrepreneurship: The mediating effect of culture.
Revista de Economía Mundial, 33 (2013), pp. 21-47
[Pinillos and Reyes, 2011]
M.J. Pinillos, L. Reyes.
Relationship between individualist-collectivist culture and entrepreneurial activity: Evidence from Global Entrepreneurship Monitor data.
Small Business Economics, 37 (2011), pp. 23-37
[Porter et al., 2002]
M.E. Porter, J.D. Sachs, J.W. McArthur.
The global competitiveness report 2001-2002.
Oxford University Press, (2002), pp. 16-25
[Sautet, 2013]
F. Sautet.
Local and systemic entrepreneurship: Solving the puzzle of entrepreneurship and economic development.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37 (2013), pp. 387-402
[Schott and Jensen, 2008]
T. Schott, K.W. Jensen.
The coupling between entrepreneurship and public policy: Tight in developed countries but loose in developing countries.
Estudios de Economía, 35 (2008), pp. 195-214
[Shane, 2009]
S. Shane.
Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy.
Small Business Economics, 33 (2009), pp. 141-149
[Urbano and Aparicio, 2016]
D. Urbano, S. Aparicio.
Entrepreneurship capital types and economic growth: International evidence.
Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 102 (2016), pp. 34-44
[Valliere and Peterson, 2009]
D. Valliere, R. Peterson.
Entrepreneurship and economic growth: Evidence from emerging and developed countries.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 21 (2009), pp. 459-480
[Van Praag and Van Stel, 2013]
M. Van Praag, A. Van Stel.
The more business owners, the merrier? The role of tertiary education.
Small Business Economics, 41 (2013), pp. 335-357
[Van Stel et al., 2005]
A. Van Stel, M.A. Carree, A.R. Thurik.
The effect of entrepreneurial activity on national economic growth.
Small Business Economics, 24 (2005), pp. 311-322
[Wennekers et al., 2007]
A.R.M. Wennekers, A.R. Thurik, A. Van Stel, N. Noorderhaven.
Uncertainty avoidance and the rate of business ownership across 21 OECD countries, 1976-2004.
Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 17 (2007), pp. 133-160
[Wennekers et al., 2005]
S. Wennekers, A. Van Stel, A.R. Thurik, P.D. Reynolds.
Nascent entrepreneurship and the level of economic development.
Small Business Economics, 24 (2005), pp. 293-309
[Wong et al., 2005]
P.X. Wong, Y.P. Ho, E. Autio.
Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: Evidence from GEM data.
Small Business Economics, 24 (2005), pp. 335-350
Copyright © 2019. AEDEM
Opciones de artículo
es en pt

¿Es usted profesional sanitario apto para prescribir o dispensar medicamentos?

Are you a health professional able to prescribe or dispense drugs?

Você é um profissional de saúde habilitado a prescrever ou dispensar medicamentos

Quizás le interese:
10.1016/j.iedeen.2021.100187
No mostrar más